Pricing of Paddy: A Case Study of Andhra Pradesh - ആർബിഐ - Reserve Bank of India
Pricing of Paddy: A Case Study of Andhra Pradesh
Issued for Discussion DRG Studies Series Development Research Group (DRG) has been constituted in Reserve Bank of India in its Department of Economic and Policy Research. Its objective is to undertake quick and effective policy-oriented research backed by strong analytical and empirical basis, on subjects of current interest. The DRG studies are the outcome of collaborative efforts between experts from outside Reserve Bank of India and the pool of research talent within the Bank. These studies are released for wider circulation with a view to generating constructive discussion among the professional economists and policy makers. Responsibility for the views expressed and for the accuracy of statements contained in the contributions rests with the author(s). There is no objection to the material published herein being reproduced, provided an acknowledgement for the source is made. From this issue onwards, DRG Studies will be published in RBI web site only and no printed copies will be made available. Director Executive Summary The farmers in the State of Andhra Pradesh are facing a situation where the viability of paddy farming has been eroded. This has been due to a steep rise in the cost of cultivation not matched by a commensurate increase in the paddy prices. The predicament faced by the farmers was rendered more acute during the year of bumper harvest of 2010-11 when the market prices of paddy ruled at a level below the minimum support price (MSP). This situation could be attributed to various structural and institutional factors prevalent in the State. This Study is an attempt to analyse these factors and to make some policy suggestions. The summary of the Study is as following. The foodgrain production in Andhra Pradesh has increased significantly in the past two decades. Rice production in the State has witnessed a growth of 3.2 per cent in the past two decades wherein the output has increased from 8 million tonnes in 1991-92 to 14.5 million tonnes in 2010-11. Notwithstanding this sharp increase, the high dependence on rainfall of well and minor irrigation renders considerable volatility in production. Of the past six years, the State has experienced favourable monsoon in five years resulting in an increased surplus in production as also an increase in the net contribution to the central pool. The rice markets are segmented in the State. The domestic consumption in the State is met mostly by the superfine varieties grown during the kharif season. The common varieties grown during the rabi season have no local market and thus they constitute the surplus. The State procurement machinery is critical for this surplus. The challenge faced by the paddy farmers in the State of Andhra Pradesh has three dimensions. First, there has been a rise in the cost of cultivation particularly in the last three years. Second, the market prices have hovered at a level below the MSP. And third, even the MSP has not been sufficient to cover the cost of cultivation which has witnessed a sharp escalation in recent years. The cost escalation has been primarily due to the increase in wage and input costs. In the last three years, wages have risen largely due to the increased bargaining power of labourers after the implementation of Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (MGNREGS). Moreover, there has been an increased demand for labour in non-agricultural sectors as well, both contributing to a general rise in wage rates. Further, the deregulation of fertiliser prices has also contributed to the rise in cost of cultivation in agriculture. In addition, there are certain factors which are unique to the State which have also contributed to high costs. These are the high rental costs in coastal districts and high fixed costs of borewell irrigation in the Telangana region. The data on costs provided by the Commission for Agricultural Costs and Prices (CACP) do not adequately capture these costs due to certain methodological reasons. Consequently, there could be instances when the cost projections made by the CACP are below the actual costs of production. Moreover, this problem is further compounded in a scenario which prevailed in the State during 2010-11 when the market prices were below the MSP and the actual procurement by the millers was also at prices which were lower than the MSP. The present situation has risen largely due to the existing structure of procurement in the State which has an overwhelming procurement of rice through the millers and only an insignificant amount of paddy is procured from the farmers. The incentive structure in paddy production in the State has certain distortions owing to the presence of some structural factors. The agrarian structure is dominated by small and marginal farmers and the markets have a situation of information asymmetry. Thus the distributional gains envisaged through the MSP do not reach the actual producers. There is, thus a need for reorienting intervention by the State through its procurement operations. Presently, there are some infrastructure bottlenecks hampering the official procurement operations, particularly in storage space and transport facilities. The model of village-level procurement by SHG-women by the State Government is an interesting innovation. There is a need to create access to institutional credit to tenant farmers. There is a need to take a comprehensive view in order to suggest short term and long term policy decisions that strengthen food security in the State as well as benefits the farming community. Acknowledgements We are deeply indebted to a large number of people that include farmers, individuals, activists, and government officials who have contributed to our understanding of the problem of paddy farmers in the State. We are pleased to acknowledge their support. Mr. Satyanarayana, and Mr. Naveen have worked hard in collecting field data and Mr. Deepak Behera has helped in estimation. We thank Dr. Vamsi Vakulabharanam, Dr. R. Vijay and Prof. Vathsala Narasimhan for their feedback on our findings. We are indebted to Prof. R. Radhakrishna and Prof. D. Narasimha Reddy for providing the encouragement to work on the issue. The study has benefitted enormously from discussions with Mr. D. Sridhar Babu, Hon Minister for Civil Supplies, Government of Andhra Pradesh, Dr. Jayaprakash Narayan, MLA, Mr. Malla Reddy, Andhra Pradesh Rythu Sangam, Mr. B. N. Yugandhar, Former IAS, Mr. Kamalakar, consultant to Department of Civil Supplies, Government of Andhra Pradesh, Mr. Muthuraman, DGM in Food Corporation of India (FCI), and Mr. V. Prakash Rao, formerly with FCI. We are extremely grateful to Suneetha for patiently editing the draft and to R. Srivatsan for his critical feedback. Ramana Murthy expresses his gratitude to the Department of Economics, University of Hyderabad, explicitly to Prof. A.V. Raja, the Head, and Prof. G. Nancharaiah, the Dean for generously lending the space to carry out the research. Finally, we are extremely thankful to Reserve Bank of India for giving the opportunity to work on the issue. We also thank RBI officials Mr. K U B Rao for providing direction in the early stages and Mr. S. Arunachalaramanan, in the final stages of the Study. Pricing of Paddy: R.V. Ramana Murthy♣ Introduction Andhra Pradesh is one of the largest producers of rice in the country and has played a key role in helping the nation achieve self-sufficiency in foodgrains. In spite of a remarkable growth story, paddy farmers in Andhra Pradesh are facing a situation where the viability of paddy farming has been eroded. On the one hand, the cost of cultivation has risen in the recent times and on the other market price of rice has ruled at a level below the cost of cultivation as well as the minimum support price (MSP). Procurement operations by the State have also not provided much succour to the farmers as majority of them did not receive MSP for their produce. In the year of bumper harvest of 2010-11, the gap between the cost of cultivation and the market prices widened further. The unviability of paddy cultivation in the State is a peculiar phenomenon as the market and institutional support which is supposed to exist for paddy much more than any other crop, except may be for wheat, is not to the desired extent. This situation owes its origin to a number of structural factors and in order to understand the present predicament, there is a need to analyse the problems in the production and the institutional structure. This study is an endeavour towards meeting such a task. A brief profile of Andhra Pradesh and its agricultural sector is provided in Section I in order to bring out the criticality of this sector in ensuring sustainable and inclusive growth in the State economy. The change in the cropping pattern over the last few decades and the importance of rice as a crop in the State is also highlighted in this section. Section II covers the important trends in production of rice in the State since the 1970s. Demand and supply situation pertaining to rice is set out in Section III. This analysis has been attempted with the objective of ascertaining whether the supply glut during the year 2010-11 is a temporary phenomenon or is permanent in nature and whether permitting export of rice is a viable solution at the current juncture. Section IV analyses the prices, costs and returns to paddy farming in the State of Andhra Pradesh. The analysis is based mainly on primary data which was collected from a survey conducted as part of this study. Section V deals with the procurement operations in the State of Andhra Pradesh. The problems faced by the paddy farmers in the State during the year 2010-11 is discussed in detail in Section VI followed by the supply chain and logistics issues in Section VII. Summary and concluding observations are set out in Section VIII. Section IX lists out certain policy suggestions based on the findings of the Study. Section I 1.1 Andhra Pradesh and Its Agriculture: A Brief Profile The State of Andhra Pradesh is geographically the fourth largest State and fifth most populated State in India. The State Domestic Product (SDP) of Andhra Pradesh recorded a growth of 7.9 per cent in the first four years of the 11th Plan period (2007-11) as compared with the nation’s GDP growth rate of 8.2 per cent. During the year 2010-11, the agricultural sector in the State contributed 25 per cent to its SDP, while industry and service sectors accounted for 50.6 per cent and 24 per cent, respectively. In spite of producing only 1/4th of SDP, the agricultural sector remains the backbone of the State economy as it is the source of livelihoods to major proportion of the State’s population. The State has a work participation rate (defined as workers per 100 population) of 38.1 per cent compared to the national average of 25.6 per cent. The State has a total workforce of 34.9 million, of which 29 million are main workers and 5.9 million are marginal workers. The agricultural and allied sector in the State directly supports 67 per cent (17.2 million main plus 4.5 million marginal workers) of its total workforce. Out of the agricultural workers, 43 per cent are cultivators and 57 per cent are agricultural labourers. The State under its land use had a net sown area of 37.2 per cent; among the rest 11.5 per cent was under current fallows, 9.2 per cent was under cultivable waste, 7.6 per cent was uncultivable waste, 22.6 per cent was under forests and 9.4 per cent was under non-agricultural use during 2008-09. The relatively large percentage of land under current fallows results in volatility in agricultural output as it fluctuates depending on the behavior of rainfall in the State. Gross Cropped Area (GCA) forms around 47 per cent of the total land, with 9.15 per cent area sown more than once. The total Net Sown Area (NSA) ranges between 11.3-12.8 million hectares, depending on the rainfall. Similarly, the GCA ranges from 12.8-13.8 million hectares. 1.2 Changing Agrarian Structure An important change that has occurred in the structure of operational landholdings in the last sixty years (during 1950-2010) is that the share of small and marginal farmers has grown from 56 to 84 per cent and the share of the area under them has increased from 18 to 49 per cent. The share of medium farmers has gone down from 33 to 16 per cent. However, the area of their landholding has increased marginally from 44 to 45 per cent. The share of big farmers has shrunk to less than 1 per cent with landholding of around 6 per cent (Table 1.1). The underlying fact about the structure is that it is overwhelmingly dominated by a class of ‘small/marginal-producer-farmers’ – a section most vulnerable to the vagaries of markets, institutions and environment. Further, there is growing tenancy in canal irrigated areas, as a section of medium farmers who played a crucial role during the green revolution has left agriculture by leasing out their lands [Parthasarathy (2002)]. They are leasing their land to landless labourers and marginal farmers. Tenancy usually takes place through oral agreements and thus this section of tenants does not have any rights under the existing laws. These tenants, unrecognisable under law due to oral tenancy, are another major vulnerable group, who lack access to institutional support. While there is no official data on the extent of tenancy, several primary studies have indicated that 70-80 per cent of cultivators in coastal Andhra are tenant farmers accounting for more than 50 per cent of land under them [Vijay (2006) and Ramachandran et al (2009)]. 1.3 Changes in the Cropping Pattern Agriculture in the State has witnessed significant changes in cropping pattern during the last four decades. These changes are marked by changes in the area under different crops as well as in agricultural seasons. First, there has been a significant shift in area under food crops to non-food crops; area under food crops declined from 70.4 per cent during 1970-73 to 53.6 per cent during 2009-11 – a fall of around 17 per cent [Table 1.2].
While food crops in general lost area to non-food crops; within food crops the area under rice increased from 24.8 per cent to 31.2 per cent. The area under coarse cereals declined during the same period. However, due to the increase in productivity, the foodgrain output has not been adversely affected; instead it experienced a long term rate of growth of 2.1 per cent. There is only a marginal addition to the area under pulses. The area withdrawn from under coarse cereals, mainly from jowar, has gone to rice, maize, cotton, oilseeds and other miscellaneous crops1. Rice is now the dominant cereal in the State and this is best illustrated by the fact that it accounted for nearly 95 per cent of the total area under non-maize cereals by 2009-10. Though this shift has enabled a faster growth of foodgrain output given the higher productivity of rice, on the flip side the State has lost the diversity in production and consumption in this virtual mono-cropping. The long term compound growth rate of production of foodgrains between 1973 and 2011 is 2.1 per cent, which is below the national average of 2.7 per cent. The last four decades can be divided into four sub-periods: the Green Revolution period during 1973-83; the post-green revolution period between 1983-91, early reforms period of 1991-2001; and the latest-reforms decade (2001-11) to understand the temporal dimension of growth in the production of foodgrains. In these sub-periods, the compound growth rate of foodgrain output was placed at 2.86 per cent, 0.53 per cent, 3.55 per cent and 3.08 per cent, respectively. In the two sub-periods in post-reform decades, foodgrains recorded impressive rates of growth of above 3 per cent. The regional pattern of the growth suggests that coastal Andhra and Telangana experienced a higher growth in foodgrain output. Rice cultivation in Rayalaseema remained stagnant. In terms of production, Coastal Andhra registered high growth during the green revolution period whereas Telangana witnessed higher growth during the last two decades. [Table 1.3]. An analysis of the sources of this growth reveals that during 1973-83 and 1983-91, the area under food grains declined. There was a shift in area under foodgrains to non-foodgrains. However, during the last one decade, i.e., 2001-11, there has been an increase in area under foodgrains. The major driving force behind the output growth has been yield during the first three decades, i.e, 1973-2001. In the last one decade, it decelerated marginally. Notably, in Telangana the yield has shown remarkable increase. This is largely due to rapid expansion of High Yielding Varieties (HYV) area under borewells. 1.4 Technology and Change in Cropping Pattern The choice of cropping pattern is dictated by the technology, irrigation and market support that are available to the farmer. In the State, the seed-fertiliser-water packaged technology along with the presence of market support for rice led to its rapid growth. Thereby, the area under HYV technology (under rice) has grown from 5.4 per cent in 1970-71 to 39.0 per cent of total area by 2010-11. Along with the HYV seeds, the use of chemical fertilisers also increased from 29.3 million tonnes in 1970-71 to 255.3 million tonnes in 2005-06. The fertiliser consumption in the State has reached levels almost equal to those of Punjab and Haryana, and consumption is 100 per cent more than its neighboring States like Tamil Nadu and Karnataka. 1.5 Growth and Nature of Irrigation Agriculture in the State is supported by three major sources of irrigation, namely canals (major irrigation), tanks (minor irrigation) and borewells & other wells (ground water irrigation). An analysis of the data on source wise irrigation in 2008-09 reveals that 65 per cent of the irrigation comes from tanks and wells, while 36 per cent of irrigation is provided by canals (Table 1.4). Thus the major source of irrigation in the State is highly dependent on rainfall. Second, the addition to surface irrigation through canals has been modest in the last thirty years. Third, there has been a decline in the tank irrigation and a steep rise in well irrigation particularly after the 1980s with the arrival of submersible pump sets and completion of rural electrification in the State [Chart 1.1].
Chart. 1.1: Source-wise Irrigation in Andhra Pradesh The regional distribution of the irrigation shows that Coastal Andhra has 57.1 per cent under canals and 43 per cent under wells and tanks. In Telangana, 15 per cent is under canals and 85 per cent is under wells and tanks. And in Rayalaseema, 25 per cent is under canals and 75 per cent is under wells and tanks. Therefore, the assured canal area is concentrated in the coastal districts while more rainfall dependent minor and ground water irrigation lies in Telangana and Rayalaseema [Chart 1.2]. Chart 1.2: Regional Distribution of Irrigation Sources 1.6 Agricultural Credit and Insurance Two notable features of institutional support to agriculture that emerged in the recent period are: first, there has been a spurt in agricultural credit in the State which increased from Rs.19,444 crore during 2006-07 to Rs.37,575 crore during 2009-10. Both term loans as well as crop loans have increased proportionately. The scheduled commercial banks are the major vehicles of credit disbursement compared to regional rural banks or co-operative societies. The disbursement to priority sector has also increased. The loan waiver given to farmers during 2005-06 has cleared a large degree of farmers’ debt accrued during the early years of the decade. Recent evidence, however, suggests that indebtedness once again seems to be on the rise. The second feature is that there has been an increase in crop insurance issued. A total sum of Rs. 837 crore was released in 2008-09 as against a premium of Rs. 201 crore. The crop insurance is about 1/4th of the cost of cultivation that fetches about Rs.1700 per acre for paddy (Socio-Economic Survey 2010-11, Planning Department, Government of Andhra Pradesh). Section II Rice Production in Andhra Pradesh: Growth and Distribution As indicated earlier in the Study, there has been a substantial increase in the rice production in the State. It has grown from a level of 4.8 million tonnes in 1970-71 to 14.4 million tonnes in 2010-11, which marks an increase of three hundred per cent (Chart 2.1). This continuous increase has been largely made possible by shift in area under coarse grains to rice. There are three broad phases in which rice cultivation has expanded in the State. First increase was witnessed during the Green Revolution period during 1971-81 when the high yielding varieties were first introduced in the Godavari-Krishna Delta areas. The second phase of this rise was during 1982-92, which was primarily due to the expansion of canal irrigation in the State. The third phase is between the years 1993-94 and 2010-11 where the increase in area was overwhelmingly contributed by the expansion in bore well irrigation. The growth in area and production is occasionally disturbed by spells of poor monsoon. All along there was a marginal deficit of production over consumption in the State even until the late 1990s [Ravi and Indrakanth (2003) and Sambi Reddy (2003)]. However, growing demand and overall stability in production and returns encouraged paddy cultivation to expand in several non-traditional areas as well. This growth not only met the PDS requirements of the State, but also led to an increased contribution to the central pool from 1993-94 onwards. The net contribution to the central pool increased from 1.8 million tonnes in 1993-94 to 5.6 million tonnes in 2010-11.Chart 2.1: Growth of Rice Production in Andhra Pradesh Another remarkable aspect about the growth is that the scale of production increased along with an increase in the per capita terms. The per capita production has increased from 132.0 kg/year in 1981-82 to 177.6 kg/year in 2010-11 [Chart 2.2]. The long term trend line of per capita production shows a positive slope. Chart 2.2: Per Capita Output of Rice in the Andhra Pradesh However, the increase has not been secular in the long run and has witnessed fluctuations in the last one decade. Production declined during the period 2002-05 due to successive monsoon failures and amounted to as low as 7.3 million tonnes in 2002-03. The average production for the decade during 2001-11 is found to be 11.5 million tonnes, which has greatly improved because of the successive increases in production since 2005-06. However, production is observed to be highly responsive to deviations in rainfall from the normal. Production has a 72 per cent correlation with rainfall index in the State. As observed earlier, about 65 per cent of area irrigated is under wells and tanks and thus rainfall is a major determinant of the level of production2. The deviations in the rainfall can cause fluctuations in acreage as well as in yield. The State has around 10 per cent of cultivated land under current fallows and this is determined by the rainfall. In the last one decade, there were four major droughts (with more than 19 per cent deficit rainfall) and during drought years, production plunged below the average level [Chart 2.1]. However, in the last five years monsoon has been favourable, barring 2009-10, leading to higher acreage and production. The long term compound growth rates of area, production and yields are set out in Table 2.1. The long term compound growth rate of rice production during 1970-2011 is 2.7 per cent. After the peak growth rates of 3.6 per cent during the initial green revolution period in 1973-83, growth rate decelerated during 1983-91. It has once again accelerated to 3.36 per cent and 3.12 per cent, during 1991-2001 and 2001-11, respectively. The growth in the decade of nineties is largely helped by the growth in yield which grew at 2.5 per cent, but stagnated during 2001-11. During 2001-11 it is the increase in area under rice that contributed to the growth in output. There are two factors that determine fluctuations in area. The first one is through changes in area under the current fallows due to changes in rainfall, and the second one is the relative price. During the period 1973-2011, the growth rate of productivity of rice in the State was placed at 1.9 per cent. The peak rate of growth in productivity was registered during the `Green Revolution’ period during 1973-83. It fell during 1983-91 and rose again during 1991-2001, before decelerating in the subsequent decade. Coastal Andhra’s productivity gains were the highest during the Green Revolution decade and Telangana region’s productivity picked up in the subsequent three decades. As observed earlier, it is the productivity of rabi that has particularly improved than that of kharif crop (Table 2.1 & 2.2). The regional distribution of rice production also underwent some change over the period. The share of coastal districts, namely, East Godavari, West Godavari, Krishna, Guntur and Nellore, in rice production has contracted in the last four decades during 1971-2009. Telangana region has increased its share and Rayalaseema’s share has come down during the same period. Telangana’s growth doubled in districts of Karimnagar, Nalgonda, Nizamabad, Mahabubnagar, Warangal and Medak in the 1990s, notably after the arrival of underground submersible pump sets. In all the regions there has been a progressive increase in absolute levels from decade to decade [Table 2.3]. Section III Demand-Supply Situation of Rice in Andhra Pradesh This brings us to the other question about how adequate is this production from the point of view of food security and food self-sufficiency in the State? Has the growth in the recent times given rise to a consistent surplus? These are pertinent questions given that Andhra Pradesh has become a major rice consuming State. The change in favour of rice from coarse cereals in consumption dominantly occurred since the introduction of two-rupee-a-kilo rice subsidy scheme by the State government in 1983-84 [Ravi and Indrakanth (2003)]. The hegemony of rice in consumption pattern is also partly responsible for the shift in demand singularly towards rice. Thereby, rice consumption and production have moved in tandem. In the eighties, rice production in the State was just enough to meet the domestic consumption and contribution to central pool was marginal. For a long time, Andhra Pradesh was not considered a rice surplus State. The public distribution system also expanded both in urban as well as rural areas. Of late, there is a popular view that output is far in excess over its local consumption as is reflected in the stagnation of market prices since 2006-07. In order to examine this view in the medium as well as long run, a simple exercise of consumption estimation has been conducted in this study by taking the per capita monthly consumption of rice in the State for rural and urban area from various NSS rounds since 1993-94. Taking the average consumption figures, the total rice demand is estimated and figures are presented in Table 3.1.3 According to the estimates [Table 3.1], the total demand for rice in the State has increased from 9.3 million tonnes in 1993-94 to 10.7 million tonnes in 2010-11. The consumption in rural areas has increased from 7.1 to 7.4 million tonnes and consumption in urban areas increased from 2.2 to 3.3 million tonnes during the same period. The consumption over the period has a slow but steady growth. In the last 18 years, the supply has fallen short of domestic demand during 5 years. For almost 10 years, supply has been sufficient to meet the level of demand or has been marginally higher. For 8 years, supply of rice has outstripped the demand by more than 10 per cent. Significantly, during all the drought years supply has fallen short of demand. Some surplus production existed during normal and excess rainfall years (with +19 per cent deviation). Since 2005-06, the surplus production has steadily grown from 1.4 to 3.6 million tonnes in 2010-11. However, during the drought year of 2009-10, supply was just sufficient to meet the demand [Chart 3.1]. Hence, the picture that emerges is that, if there is normal season-weighted rainfall, there is a surplus. According to our projections, the overall consumption in the coming five years may increase only up to 11.2 million tonnes by 2016-17. Besides this, in the wake of the new Food Security Act 2011 coming into implementation, according to the estimates of Department of Civil Supplies, Government of Andhra Pradesh, there may be a need to procure another 0.45 million tonnes of rice in the State. The overall requirement in the State will go up to 11.65 million tonnes, which is still below the average production of the last one decade.4 Chart 3.1: Demand-Supply of Rice in Andhra Pradesh According to the Engel’s law, as per capita income increases, the proportion of expenditure on food declines. Further, when per capita income increases, the expenditure on cereals decreases as people are likely to shift to protein and fat-based diets. There is some evidence for such decline in cereal demand in the State too. The real per capita monthly consumer expenditure from 1993-94 up to 2010-11 has increased threefold in case of rural and fivefold among urban population. The average per capita monthly rice consumption in rural areas has declined from 11.5 to 11.2 kg and from 10.1 to 9.3 kg in urban areas during the same period (Table 3.2). If the latest 66th Round NSS data of 2009-10 is considered, the average per capita consumption of rice has fallen to 11.2 kg/month for rural and 9.2 kg/month for urban. Therefore, even accounting for cereal dominated dietary patterns, the future demand for rice in the next five years, going by the expenditure elasticity of food, is not going to be more than 11.64 million tonnes. This is a conservative estimate, the actual demand could be even less. If projections are made using the 66th round of NSSO, it drops by another 5 million tonnes. Even after considering substitution and income effect and after providing an additional 3 kg per head under new Food Security Bill, the additional demand is not likely to go up by more than one million tonne in the State. Another dimension of domestic demand in the State is the variety-wise segmentation. There is an increasing preference for consuming fine and superfine varieties of rice produced only during kharif season, even among the sections with relatively low income. The domestic demand for the superfine varieties in the State is to a tune of about 5 million tonnes, which constitutes 75 per cent of total production in kharif season. Clearly, there is not much of surplus in superfine and fine rice in the State. However, part of the Kharif and whole of rabi produce of common (inferior) varieties has no local market. All the common variety rice is surrendered for procurement. Such rice, when given through PDS, particularly to the non-poor, finds its way to secondary markets. Major portion of the common rice is made into parboiled rice, which is procured by FCI for Kerala and South Tamil Nadu’s consumption. It has no local market in the State. The surplus production is in the common variety and not in the superfine and fine variety. Overall, in the recent period, there is seemingly a surplus production of rice in the State subject to the performance of the monsoon. However, there is a need to take the overall need in the country before one declares this as a genuine surplus over the country’s overall requirement. Moreover in the State also, surplus of rice is in the case of common varieties and not fine and super fine varieties. Section IV 4.1 Farm Harvest Prices and Minimum Support Prices It is well known that since the launching of the Green Revolution, providing a stable market environment through remunerative price has been central to incentivise the foodgrain production in the country. It is this stable market environment and remunerative prices that encouraged the growth of foodgrain production in the country. MSP has become the major instrument to keep the market prices from plunging below the cost of production. However, there have been concerns about the MSP announced by the Central Government, that the all-India average cost of production has often not covered the costs in several States with higher than average cost of production. Second, given the long time-lag in processing the cost of cultivation data by the CACP, the annual projections have been based on data which at times are dated, a practice that is viewed as creating discrepancies between the actual and projected costs. Coming to the case of Andhra Pradesh, the paddy prices in the last two decades have moved in tandem with the MSP, barring the last two years. The farm harvest prices have mostly remained marginally above MSP for most of the years. Since 1998-99, the farm harvest prices of rice have remained marginally above the MSP for both Grade-A and common varieties [Charts 4.1a and 4.1b]. However, during 2010-11, the farm harvest prices of both the varieties have fallen below the MSP. In fact, a closer look suggests that as far as prices of common variety are concerned, not only have they remained below the MSP since 2008-09 by Rs.50-60, in 2010-11 they have fallen short by nearly Rs.200 [Table 4.1]. The actual prices that farmers received have remained even lower during the year. Chart 4.1a: Market Price and MSP (Grade-A) Chart 4.1b: Market Price and MSP (Common) Moreover, it is not only the prices of common varieties of paddy that have fallen below MSP, but even those of fine and super fine varieties have fallen to the level of MSP (Grade-A) and even below. This has happened for the first time. The Food Corporation of India considers only the length of grain as the basic criterion for grading. Even some varieties which have good demand in the market due to their cooking quality do not come under Grade-A. Some superfine varieties are considered as Grade-A5. The surplus production in superfine rice during 2010-11 has pushed their prices below the MSP. However, its cost of production is higher than common variety because it is of longer duration and is a low yielding crop. The underlying fact is that the market prices of all varieties were below the MSP during the bumper harvest of 2010-11; market prices of common varieties have been consistently below the MSP since 2008-09. These are indicative of two major issues: first, procurement mechanism in the State has not been able to assure the MSP to the farmers and; second, there must be a finer gradation system to be adopted by the procurement agencies so that the superfine rice receives its due protection from the vagaries of the markets. Before we examine the returns to farming due to this situation, it is in order to examine as to how far minimum support prices have covered the actual costs of production. 4.2.1 Cost of Cultivation: The Sample Study for Andhra Pradesh There are three major issues in the State in relation to returns to paddy farming. First, there is an increasing concern that the minimum support prices have not adequately covered the cost of production for the past three years. Second, even the under-priced MSP is actually not received by the farmers. Third, farm harvest prices of paddy have remained less than MSP due to ineffective presence of procurement agencies in the market. We shall examine these three issues in the section. As stated earlier, it is difficult to make a realistic estimate of the cost of cultivation based on secondary data. The official data on cost of cultivation is arrived at based on an elaborate methodology but it has certain limitations. The differences in the costs between States are not adequately captured in the construction of the national average. Second, there is a view that CACP data underestimates the actual costs6. Even the available data with CACP is collected from a thin sample. In the State also, the differences within the regions of the State may not be effectively measured. In order to get a realistic picture on cost of cultivation, the present study has collected primary data on cost of cultivation, prices, yield, acreage, varieties grown and marketing for the year 2010-11 in the State through structured questionnaires. The study covered 192 households in 13 villages from eight districts, namely East Godavari, Krishna, Karimnagar, Nizamabad, Warangal, Medak, Nalgonda and Mahaboobnagar. The sample households and the villages are based on random selection. The districts selected are all primary rice growing ones spanning in three agro-climatic regions namely, K-G Delta, North Telangana and South Telangana. East Godavari and Krishna in the sample are completely under canal irrigation, while other districts have both canal and well irrigation. The class distribution of 192 sample households constituted 39, 118 and 35 marginal, small and medium operational households [Table 4.2.1], forming 20.3 per cent, 61.5 per cent and 18.7 per cent, respectively, in the total sample. The land held by these three classes is 15 per cent, 49 per cent and 36 per cent, respectively. Among these 69.3 per cent of the farmers are owner-cultivators, 15.6 per cent are owner-tenants7, and 15.0 per cent are tenants (which includes 1.5 per cent sharecroppers) (Table 4.2.2). Owner cultivation is found to be prominent in Telangana, while tenancy is dominantly observed in coastal districts. In East Godavari and Krishna, tenancy is between 60-80 per cent. The pattern observed in the sample is in tune with the average distribution of operational households in the State as observed earlier. The growing tenancy in the State has been noted by several other researchers [Ramachandran et al (2009), Vijay (2003)].
4.2.2 Estimated Cost of Cultivation The cost of cultivation scheme developed by the Commission for Agricultural Costs and Prices defines five cost concepts, namely, (i) Cost A1 (all fixed and variable paid out costs excluding rent), (ii) Cost A2 (Cost A1+ rent), (iii) Cost A2+ (Family Labour (FL)), (iv) Cost B1 (Cost A1 + Interest on value of owned fixed assets excluding land), (v) Cost B2 (Cost A2 + imputed rent on own land), (vi) Cost C1 ( Cost B1+ imputed family labour); (vii) Cost C2 (Cost B2 + imputed family labour) ; (viii) Cost C2* (Cost C2 using Minimum Wages if they are higher than market wages); (ix) Cost C3 (cost C2*+10 per cent managerial input over C2*). Cost A2 + FL includes rent as well as family labour and is relevant cost for tenant farmer, Cost B1 and B2 are relevant for small and marginal farmers, and cost C1 and C3 are relevant costs for supervisory landlord farmer. The respective cost of cultivation is converted into cost of production per quintal by applying the yield. The estimated cost of cultivation per acre and per hectare is given Table 4.2.3 and Table 4.2.4. There are no notable class differences between farmers in the cost of cultivation, while there are significant differences between regions. Therefore, a region-wise analysis is presented in the tables. From Table 4.2.3, when paid-out costs (Cost A1) are considered, we observe that they range between Rs.18,162-24,623 per acre. The average paid out cost is Rs. 20,380 per acre. Barring Mahabubnagar, differences between the regions are not very large in terms of paid-out costs (Cost A1). This is primarily because the wage and input costs (which together constitute 50 per cent) are more or less similar. The Cost A1 per acre ranged between Rs.24,623 in Krishna district and Rs.18,162 in Medak. The cost of cultivation in delta region is Rs.21,623 in East Godavari and Rs.24,623 in Krishna. But there are significant differences in Cost A2 between regions. The Cost A2 on average is 30 per cent higher in coastal districts compared to Telangana districts. Consequently, these differences remain the same in Cost A2 + FL, Cost B2, Cost C2 and the overall cost C3. They are all higher in coastal districts. There are two reasons for this: first rental costs are quite high in coastal regions. Second, their labour component is relatively still high. In Telangana region, the farmers are saving labour costs by hiring harvesters. The cost C3 (total cost) is 20-25 per cent higher in coastal districts as compared to the Telangana region. This is more evident when the break-up of cost of cultivation across regions is considered. On average, hired labour costs constitute about 27.4 per cent, material inputs cost 21.5 per cent, machine labour costs 16.33 per cent, rental costs amount to around 13.95 per cent, interests and marketing costs are about 7.1 per cent and miscellaneous costs are 4.3 per cent for the State [Table 4.2.4]. As labour costs constitute more than one fourth of the costs, when wage rates have gone up substantially in the last three years, the overall cost has substantially increased. The important differences between delta regions and the other regions is that in the former, rental cost is about 30 per cent and labour cost too is about the same. The rents are maximum in Godavari districts followed by Krishna district, where these are 30 bags (75 kg) and 20 bags per annum, respectively. The rents have gone up with large number of landless and marginal farmers competing for a fixed amount of land available for lease. When wage rates were low at Rs.150 and Rs.40 for male and female workers, respectively, paddy farming used to leave some surplus to tenant farmer, but once the wage rates have gone up to Rs. 300 and Rs.125 for the same categories since 2007-08, the steep costs have overtaken the revenues. In Telangana districts, the fixed costs, marketing and transport costs and machine costs together constitute around 65 per cent. In Telangana region farmers have responded to wage rise by shifting to harvesters. Though grass worth Rs.1500 is lost in using harvester, they save a cost of around Rs.5000 per acre. Harvesters are also available in the region which can harvest maize as well as paddy. The rest of the costs comprise of labour and material input costs. The interest costs are the same across the districts. There is a thin margin left to meet the different paid-out costs. In the absence of rental costs and with the prevailing prices, paddy cultivators in Telangana are just around the break-even point. The increase in wage costs and fertiliser costs have reduced the margin in this region as well. The differences between our estimates and CACP figures are presented in Table 4.2.5. There is a wide divergence between CACP figures and our estimates. This is primarily because CACP in making projections for 2010-11 used the data of 2006-07, which may not be very relevant. Second, the projections by CACP are made based on labour cost index and input cost index which may not adequately capture the actual costs incurred in the State. Third, CACP methodology may have underestimated the marketing costs, transport costs, interest costs, rental costs, family labour, attached labour and machine labour prevalent in the State. The State Government of Andhra Pradesh is also preparing its own estimates on cost of cultivation [Table 4.2.6]. However, these estimates do not consider transport costs, marketing costs, labour costs in applying fertiliser and pesticides and the interest costs.8 For this reason, there is 20 per cent variation between our estimates and the figures provided by the State Government. During the field study, farmers recalled in their narratives that until the year 2006-07, the prices they received were remunerative. However, in their perception, the steep escalation of costs occurred with the implementation of MGNREGA. Along with that, the PDS scheme with two-rupee price may have also resulted in greater bargaining power of labour. Telangana farmers have responded to this increase in labour costs with increased mechanisation however coastal districts farmers continue to incur high labour costs in the absence of such substitution. The cost of cultivation when, expressed as cost per quintal is referred to as cost of production and is useful to compare with the prices and assess the returns. According to the estimates, the costs A1, B1 and C1 – all relevant costs for owner cultivators stood at Rs.847, Rs.849 and Rs.1045 per quintal. The MSP for the year at Rs.1030 covered the paid-out costs of owner-cultivators. However it does not cover their family labour. The costs A2, A2+FL, B2 and C2 stood at Rs. 991, Rs.1187, Rs.1131, and Rs.1327, respectively. We can see that except Cost A2, the MSP did not cover any of the costs which are relevant for tenant farmers. Inclusion of cost of family labour further widens this gap between the cost and MSP. Among the districts, Mahabubnagar has high cost of production because of the low productivity in the region. The overall cost C3 is highest in East Godavari and Krishna at Rs. 1837, and Rs. 1952, respectively. These are almost Rs.600 more than the costs in other districts, (except Mahabubnagar). In other Telangana districts, the overall cost C3 ranges between Rs.1137-1318. This huge difference in cost of production between the two broad regions is accounted for by the high rental costs and labour costs in coastal districts. Cost of production in Mahabubnagar is high because of lower yields on the one hand and higher labour costs on the other. The average cost of production between the two broad regions, namely, coastal Andhra and Telangana is presented in the Table 4.2.7. The received prices in coastal Andhra covered only paid out costs of Cost A1, which is the paid-out cost of owner-cultivator and that of tenant. It has also not covered the full cost of both categories. In Telangana, the received price has covered both the paid-out costs of owner-cultivator as well as the tenant. But there too, it has not covered the full cost (Cost C1 and Cost C2). Similarly, the MSP has covered only paid out cost of owner-cultivator in Andhra and both types of farmers in Telangana. However, it too did not cover the full cost in either of the regions. This substantial difference in cost of production between the two broad regions is accounted for by high rental costs and labour costs in coastal districts. 4.2.3 Negative Returns The (estimated) returns on paddy farming for the two regions, namely, Coastal Andhra and Telangana, present an interesting picture [Table 4.2.8]. The returns over Cost A1 are positive in both regions, though prices barely covered the paid-out costs for owner-cultivator in Andhra with a return of 2.4 per cent, however in Telangana the cultivator received a 12 per cent return. Owner-cultivator class dominates in Telangana region and has been able to break-even. However, as regards the return on full cost, namely Cost C1, C2 and C3, the returns are negative in both the regions. Compared to Telangana, the situation in Coastal Andhra appears to be alarming with a loss of 109 per cent over Cost C3, 90 per cent over Cost C2 and 24.5 per cent over Cost C1. Cost A2, C2 and C3 include rental component and thus the losses in Coastal Andhra region over these are much higher, because of high rents. These substantial differences in the returns between the two regions are evident when we look at the composition of cost of cultivation. The rent-labour-input costs in Andhra region together constitute a lion’s share of 79 per cent of the total cost in the former. In Telangana, the labour-machine-input-fixed costs constitute 64 per cent. The labour use is reduced in the former by the use of harvesters. The application of fertilisers is higher in Telangana, which possibly explains the marginally higher productivity observed in our sample. Now coming to analytical aspect of cost conservation, in Coastal Andhra the rental and labour component being exceptionally higher is entirely because of agrarian structure dominated by tenancy relations. The tenants pay high rents and avoid use of machinery to save the grass and use of green gram as the second crop which is planted even before the harvesting of the first crop. Thus this structure does not have scope to mechanise and optimise the costs. Thus what seems to have happened in the coastal Andhra regions is that while rental costs have gone up due to active lease market, the rise in labour costs since 2007-08 has also been steep. In our sample villages, it is reported that the wages for male workers have reached Rs.300 from Rs.150 and wages for female workers have doubled from Rs.75 to Rs.150. Evidence from secondary sources also corroborates this rise in nominal wages which was observed from the field study. In the light of high rents, the high labour costs have rendered tenant cultivation unviable (Chart 4.2). Chart 4.2: Break-up of Cost of Cultivation in Coastal Andhra and Telangana 4.2.4. The Increase in Wage Costs Evidence available from the field survey indicates the substantial increase in the nominal wages as the major reason behind cost escalation in the recent period. In addition, there is some evidence from the State level data on nominal wages, published by the Directorate of Economics and Statistics which supports our findings. According to this data, the nominal wages in the State have risen at an annual compound growth rate of 12.6 per cent for male workers and 13.3 per cent for female workers during the period 2000-10. The growth of nominal wages is particularly steep during 2007-10. In these three years, the cumulative growth of nominal wages for male workers has been 91.3 per cent while it has been 102 per cent for female labourers (Table 4.2.9 and Chart 4.3). Even in real terms, the wages have risen for male and female labourers by 52 and 59 per cent, respectively, during the period9. While it is tempting to attribute the sharp rise in rural wages to the implementation of Mahatma Gandhi Rural Employment Guarantee Act since 2007-08 in the State, this explanation falls outside the purview of this study10. This piece of evidence, however, corroborates our field level observations that wages have gone up substantially since 2007-08. When such price shocks occur in the labour market, which cannot be met from productivity gains which happen in small increments in the long run the viability and profitability is negatively impacted. Chart 4.3: Average Nominal Wages in A.P
Source: Department of Economics and Statistics, Govt. of Andhra Pradesh
4.3 ‘Crop Holiday’ in the Coastal Region A grimmer situation is unfolding in the coastal districts. In East Godavari and Krishna districts, the rental costs constitute 40 to 35 per cent of the total cost. These are far in excess over the legal maximum of 16 per cent. The second biggest cost is the labour cost which is up to 35 and 36 per cent. The reason for the high rents is that an increasing number of landowners who have left agriculture are holding the land for speculative purposes. The high proportion of landless agricultural labourers and marginal farmers in the region compete to lease-in the land among themselves resulting in a sharp increase in the rents in the region11. The labour costs are about 35 - 36 per cent presently, which have also gone up from the earlier 10 to 35 per cent and this has wiped out the 20-25 per cent surplus that the tenant used to earn. This is one of the major reasons why farmers in East Godavari went on to declare ‘crop holiday’ as a protest [Appendix]. The paddy cultivation in the region does not seem to be sustainable in the existing structure of costs. In fact most of the landowners in this region have diversified into non-agricultural activities. Many have become the commission agents, fertiliser dealers, money lenders, millers, etc. Marginal and (some) small farmers have remained in agriculture due to lack of alternate employment opportunities. It is this remaining class of agricultural labour and marginal farmers which forms the tenant-peasant class. The rentier-middlemen class is able to extract a steady surplus from the agricultural labour population12. This broad class formation, evident in Coastal Andhra from East Godavari to Nellore districts characterises the political economy of agrarian relations [these trends are observed by Ramachandran et al (2009)]. The labour class has been able to increase their share due to MGNREGS and PDS but tenant farmers have been adversely affected by the increase in labour costs combined with high rents. On the contrary, in Telangana in the absence of substantial canal irrigation and extensive dependence on groundwater, farming in general does not leave much room for tenant cultivation. Hence, the owner-cultivation remains the dominant formation. The instability of irrigation, the dependence on erratic rainfall, maintenance of motors in the face of erratic power supply, and labour problem have reduced the surplus of big farmers. The labour constraints severely limit the viability of supervisory-farming, even in the classes of middle and big farmers. It is the small and marginal farmers using family labour who are able to save the paid-out costs, and carry out subsistence-farming. If one seeks to find a solution without altering the present agrarian structure and distribution, revising the MSP may appear as a logical solution. However, this is a short-term solution as revision in MSP will cause a matching rise in retail prices triggering a wage spiral which will in turn affect the labour cost and the overall costs incurred by the farmers. Therefore, there must be some cost reducing mechanism that needs to be explored. For instance, mechanisation, as the way Telangana farmers have adopted, can reduce the labour costs by around 10 per cent. The institutional credit access to the tenant farmer can reduce the cost by 5 per cent. Rationalisation of rents can also save up to 15 per cent. Section V Procurement and Policy As indicated earlier, rice production in the State was barely sufficient to meet the demand and thus the State had a marginal contribution to the central pool. The market prices always tended to be above the MSP, because of the strong local market. Hence, the case of direct procurement of paddy to support the market price did not arise in the past. Food Corporation of India, however, had to procure rice for central pool as well as to meet the requirements of the PDS. The only way was to impose a levy on millers, who were more inclined to sell in the local market or outside the State. Initially, the compliance with levy was not forthcoming because the levy price was far below the market price. In 1983, when the PDS in the State was revamped and expanded to include all poor households by the State Government in the 2-rupee per kg rice scheme under PDS, the State instituted a mechanism wherein the millers were required to deliver 50 per cent for State procurement and the rest could be sold in the open market. The State issued levy order under Essential Commodities Act (ESMA) and obtained its procurement13. The reasonable price for the farmers and assured market for the millers created some stability which in turn encouraged the production of rice in the State [Sambi Reddy (2003)]. From the early nineties onwards, as production of rice expanded, millers emerged as the dominant intermediary who acquired most of the produce in the market as paddy and sold it as milled raw rice. They sold most of rabi varieties as boiled and raw rice to FCI. As a result, the net contribution to the central pool began to grow. In the nineties, when production was growing at 3.2 per cent, procurement grew at 8.0 per cent per annum. During 2001-11, procurement increased at 3.9 per cent while production grew at 3.1 per cent. Leaving the years 2002-05, when the successive droughts have severely affected the rice output in the State, the procurement in the State continued to increase in the past two decades to reach the record levels of 90.6 million tonnes in 2008-09 and 90.8 million tonnes in 2010-11 (Chart 5.1). This is roughly one fourth of the rice procurement for the central pool in the country. While the increased contribution to central pool is welcome from the point of view of national food security, the policy of procuring rice from the millers and negligible amount of paddy from the farmers resulted in a situation where the farmers did not receive the MSP, especially in case of the rabi crop. Chart .5.1. Production, Procurement and PDS in Andhra Pradesh The combined procurement of paddy by the Andhra Pradesh Civil Supplies Corporation (APCSC) and Food Corporation of India (FCI) has remained between 0.3-0.5 million tonne during the period 2001-01 to 2009-10. This is 2-3 per cent of paddy output in the State, while around 97 per cent of paddy was purchased by the millers [Table 5.1] However, FCI’s purchase of rice from millers varied depending upon the overall level of production, between 38-75 per cent. Though the levy is fixed at 75 per cent, the extent of stocks surrendered by the millers to FCI depended on the extent of output. During bumper years, mills sold more rice to FCI and during poor harvest years they sold it in the market. Ironically, this mechanism does not seem to have served the interests of the farmers as much as it has served the millers. Under the existing rules of rice procurement, millers are supposed to pay MSP to the farmers, and are required to submit the proof of this payment to FCI. However, it is not difficult for the millers to produce such certification from the revenue department. Millers avoid making the payment of MSP to the farmers quite often by citing several reasons, such as grain having higher moisture level, discolouration, and other quality issues. Traditional practices of quality testing by grinding in palms and visual inspection makes room for arbitrary assessment. Farmer is often not in a position to bargain or take back the produce. Except large farmers who are generally aware about the millers’ malpractices, most of the small and marginal farmers sell their produce to the millers. These problems can be overcome to some extent if paddy procurement takes place at the village level. A comparison between the procurement structure in different States between paddy and rice reveals the difference in procurement operations in the State of Andhra Pradesh and other major rice producing States [Table 5.2 & 5.3]. For example, in the years 2008-09 and 2009-10, in States like Punjab, Chhattisgarh, Tamil Nadu and Orissa and Haryana – all prominent rice growing States, the procurement directly from the farmers is far more compared to levy procurement from millers. Particularly, during the bumper harvest year of 2010-11, State agencies procured major share directly from the farmers. This significantly eliminates the role of the millers and ensures MSP to the farmers. While the historical evolution of procurement in each State may be different, the important point is that a stronger presence of State weakens the role of the middlemen. Therefore, in Andhra Pradesh, there is a need for bringing about a reorientation in the procurement policy.
The general practice in the coastal districts is that due to strong interlinked transactions, farmers sell the output to millers through commission agents. Agents lift the output at the farm gate. Millers procure the grain through proxy agents. The absence of an alternative agency at the village level makes the agent as a monopsonist. Big farmers finance the cultivation from their own capital and hoard the grain for an opportune time to sell. However, the small and marginal farmers, particularly the tenants cannot wait for long and dispose their produce for any price that the agent is ready to offer. There is no practice of taking the produce to the mandies. For this reason, the procurement operations by the government agencies is almost absent in the coastal districts. Market yards are active in Telangana and farmers transport the produce to the yard and the official procurement agencies are relatively more active. Even there, Andhra Pradesh State Civil Supplies Corporation (APSCSC) has only procurement centers at mandal and district levels. The farmers in remote villages generally sell it to the local traders. Section VI 6.1. Problem of Bumper Crop and Low Prices in 2010-11 The year 2010-11 was an exceptional year which witnessed rainfall of 22 per cent above normal. Though, cyclone Lila damaged the standing crop in November in some areas in Delta districts, it immensely helped the rabi crop. Not only the kharif outturn delivered well at 7.5 million tonnes, the rabi that produced 6.8 million tonnes was an exceptionally high level of output. The rabi output was higher than the previous record of 5.9 million tonnes in 2008-09. All rice growing districts recorded higher production than their previous records. West Godavari, for example, produced 2.24 million tonnes of paddy, Karimnagar 2.04 million tonnes, pushing East Godavari district to third place. The total production of paddy in the State was placed at 21.5 million tonnes. The high production levels in the past six years were helped by favourable monsoons, the latest being the peak. The ban on exports of superfine variety rice for the past three years reportedly led to accumulation of stocks with the millers. The bumper rabi crop in 2010-11 resulted in a situation of plenty. The APSCSC, which is the main procurement agency for paddy, prepares the kharif and rabi plans of procurement based on the advance estimates of production given by the Directorate of Economics and Statistics14. There are certain problems in the data collection. The village level revenue staff often under-reports the area sown and sometimes there is under estimation of yield by the agricultural department. As a result, the projected output is often underestimated (the error could be up to 10 per cent, Centre for Economic and Social Studies, 1997). Due to this, the market arrivals during the year 2010-11 exceeded the anticipated quantity. Due to the glut in the market, millers did not lift the paddy. Consequently, the Government made arrangements to receive the huge inflows of grain in the mandies for which initially the requisite infrastructural and institutional support was inadequate. Lack of godown storage, gunny bags and transport shortage further hampered the procurement operations. The government finally procured 2.5 million tonnes15. 6.2 The IKP Innovation One innovation that the Government introduced during 2010-11 was to procure paddy with the help of SHG groups. The SHG groups had earlier procured maize for Andhra Pradesh State Cooperative Marketing Federation. There are more than 3000 women groups at village level. In several villages these women are given training in handling income earning activities, including the agricultural procurement. These SHGs are governed under a governmental program called Indira Kranthi Padhakam (IKP). Relying on their expertise, when the government assigned the paddy procurement during 2010-11, these SHGs have proved to be an instant success. They procured 1.69 million tonnes (which is 90 per cent of APSCSC’s procurement). This could enable the Government to make a procurement which was higher as compared to the previous years. There are certain important lessons to be learnt from the developments in 2010-11. In the past, it was generally held that procurement from farmers was not needed because market prices tended to be higher than MSP. However, during 2010-11, it was recognised that this is only partially true. In fact, markets have always been uneven. In many remote villages, commission agents paid less than MSP. The absence of the State machinery to procure paddy, particularly in the coastal districts strengthened the interlocked markets of credit, input and output. Farmers had little bargaining power in such interlocked transactions. In Telangana districts, the active procurement by the State could break the interlocked markets to some extent. 6.3. Levy Policy and the Role of the Millers In any system of market exchange, there must be an optimal distribution of incentives between units engaged in production and units engaged in exchange in order to provide enabling conditions for the growth in output. In paddy markets in the State, millers earned disproportionate profits in levy as well as through open market sales. Under levy, the millers usually managed to pay less to the farmer by citing quality issues. To illustrate, during 2010-11, if miller paid the MSP to the farmer, which is Rs.1030, costs of one quintal rice to the miller is Rs.1537. FCI paid miller a levy price of Rs.1750, which is inclusive of cess, cost of gunny bag, transport and hamali and milling charges. In principle this leaves the miller with Rs.200 as the residual profit per quintal. In practice, millers make a further margin by paying less to the farmers. Thus the millers made profits whereas farmers incurred a loss of Rs.430! In case of superfine BPT variety rice, during 2010-11, the market price of paddy fell to Rs.1050 per quintal16, which costs the miller Rs.1567 per quintal. After incurring the incidentals, milling charges and sales tax, miller incurred a cost of Rs.1850 and sold it in the wholesale market between Rs.2300-2500. This fetched a profit of Rs.450 to Rs.550. The retail margins were around 2 per cent, hence retail prices were between Rs.2400-Rs.2550. Earlier the State procured rice from millers by imposing levy, as the millers did not prefer to sell paddy to the FCI because market price used to be higher than the levy price paid by FCI. As the production improved in the last twenty years, market price has relatively stagnated and the levy price is revised up to match the market price. The FCI procurement has now emerged as the major market for the millers and the new rice levy of 75 per cent with 25 per cent being parboiled provided a lucrative, stable and captive market. Section VII Supply Chain and Logistical Issues An effective grain procurement mechanism presupposes supporting infrastructure, particularly warehousing, transport, weighing, testing equipment and man-power. The supply chain management engages with cost-effective methods of storage and disposal. In the State of Andhra Pradesh, these issues did not receive due attention in the recent times. The total warehousing capacity in the State with public and private warehouses (including space available with rice mills) is about 8.5 million tonnes. Out of these, godown space under FCI, Central Warehousing Corporation and State Warehousing Corporation for foodgrains is about 4.7 million tonnes (55 per cent of total storage capacity (Table 7.1). In a regular kharif season, a volume of about 10 million tonnes of paddy arrives in a span of two months during November and December and much of it is acquired by the mills and is milled. Out of the total milled rice, FCI procures up to 3 million tonnes during the period January to March. In any given year, there is not much storage problem until April. However, from April and May onwards, while the kharif rice is still lying with FCI, the rabi rice arrivals start constraining the storage capacity available with the FCI. There is a monthly total outflow of 0.7 million tonnes (0.3 million tonnes for PDS in the State and about 0.4 million tonnes to out of State) from the warehouses. By the end of June, the free space available with the warehouses is only around 2.7 million tonnes. The rabi arrivals amount to around 5-6 million tonnes, depending upon the level of production, all of which goes for FCI procurement. The outflows are constrained by shortage of wagons as the railways are not able to assign adequate wagons. The current allocation is only 40 rakes a month which means virtually one goods train, which goes all the way to Kerala, unloads and returns. Thus the inflows are much higher than the outflows in this season, resulting in severe shortage of godown space. According to FCI, there is a storage deficit of 1.9 million tonnes from June to August in case the rabi crop output exceeds 5 million tonnes of production. When FCI slows down procurement due to lack of storage space, it in turn slows down the milling pace, causing a buildup of inventories with millers. This slows down the purchases from farmers, which in turn depresses the price. There are two solutions to this problem, first is to immediately create more godown space. Second, is to allocate more rakes to the State. State Government recently announced a plan to create 2.5 million tonnes as additional capacity in the coming four years, of which 0.4 million tonnes space is likely to be added in the current financial year. If this additional capacity is created, it can take the total storage capacity with public agencies to 7.2 million tonnes, which should be fairly adequate [Table 7.2]. State Government has requested for an allocation of 200 rakes, which is also an important mechanism to keep the regular outflow. However, since no more than 0.4 million tonnes additional space is being made available this year, there is a need to achieve greater level of efficiency in offloading. Therefore, creating additional storage and rail transport are critical for an efficient and effective procurement system in the State. Section VIII Conclusion In this study, we have addressed some of the serious concerns of paddy farming and public policy in Andhra Pradesh in the recent period. The broad conclusions are as follows:
Section IX Policy Suggestions:
References: CESS, (1987) Statistical Systms for Multilevel Planning: Findings of the Report on Improvements to A.P. Statistical System, Center for Economic and Social Studies, Hyderabad. Mittal, Surabhi (2008) “Demand-Supply Projections of Food in India” working paper no.209, ICRIER, New Delhi. Parthasarathy, B (2002): “Changing Agrarian Structure and Nature of Transition in Post-Green Revolution Period” in Krishna Rao, Y V and Subrahmanyam edited Development of Andhra Pradesh: 1956-2001 A Study of Regional Disparities, N.R.R Research Centre, Hyderabad. Parthasarathy, B et al (1984) “Critical Indices of Transition to Capitalism within Agriculture and the Changing Agrarian Structure in Godavari Delta of A.P” in Krishna Rao, Y V et al Peasant Farming and Growth of Capitalism in Indian Agriculture, Visalandhra Publication House, Vijayawada. Radhakrishna, R and Indrakanth (1987) “Effects of Rice Market Interventions in India: the Case of Andhra Pradesh” in Evaluating Rice Market Intervention Policies, Some Asian Examples, Asian Development Bank, Manila. Rahula Shastri and Kishan Rao (2009) Andhra Pradesh Economy: Dynamic Transformation with a Focus on Regional Disparities, National Academi of Development, Hyderabad. Ramanamurthy, RV (2011) “Paddy Glut and Farmers’ Crisis in Andhra Pradesh” Economic and Political Weekly, vol.46, no.29. Ramachandran, V K, Vikas Rawat and Madhura Swaminathan (2009) edited Socio-Economic Surveys of Three Villages in Andhra Pradesh, Tulika Books, New Delhi. Ravi, C and Indrakanth (2003) “Food Security and Public Distribution System” in Hanumantha Rao CH and Mahendra Dev edited Andhra Pradesh Development: Economic Reforms and Challenges Ahead, Center for Economic and Social Studies, Hyderabad. Reddy, D. Narasimha (2007) “Half a Century of Travails of Agriculture in Andhra Pradesh”, Vasanthi Memorial Lecture, published by Vasanthi Memorial Trust, Kakinada. Varkey, Shinu (2009) “Foodgrains Production in Andhra Pradesh: A Study of Trends and Patterns”, unpublished M.Phil dissertation submitted to Dept of Economics, University of Hyderabad. Vijay R (2006) “Agrarian Structure and Agrarian Relations: Illustrations from Village Studies” in Studies in Humanities and Social Sciences, Vol.2, No.1. Vamsi, Vakulabharanam, N Purandra Prasad, K Laxminarayana and Sudheer Kilaru (2011) “Understanding the Andhra Crop Holiday Movement”, Economic and Political Weekly, vol.XL IV, No.50, Dec 10, p.13-15. Subba Rao, K (1978) Rice Marketing System and Compulsory Levies in Andhra Pradesh: A Study of Public Intervention in Food Grain Marketing, IEG-Allied Publishers, New Delhi. Reports: Mohan Kanda Committee Report On The Problems Of Farmers In Crop Holiday Affected Mandals of East Godavari District in A.P Government of Andhra Pradesh, (2011). Kharif Plan for A.P (2011-12):, Food Corporation of India, Regional Office, Hyderabad. Reports of Commission for Agricultural Costs and Prices (1983 to 99). Socio-Economic Survey (2010-11), Department of Planning, Andhra Pradesh. Statistical Abstracts (2002-2009), Directorate of Economics and Statistics, Government of Andhra Pradesh. Cost of Cultivation Manual (2003) published by Commission for Agricultural Costs and Prices, Ministry of Agriculture, Government of India. Appendix ‘Crop Holiday’ Movement in East Godavari The coastal districts of Andhra Pradesh were hit by cyclone `Lila’ in the month of November 2010 and kharif crop was badly damaged. East Godavari was the worst hit. Though the second crop of paddy has come up well, the prices took a plunge. Millers offered a price of Rs.700-800 per quintal for paddy. The cost of cultivation on the other hand has gone up since 2007-08. This has adversely affected the farmers. The position of tenant farmers who do most of the cultivation was the worst. On the one hand they did not have access to institutional credit and no protection against natural calamities (land owners have access to institutional support like credit and insurance) and on the other the rents increased up to 50 per cent of the output. All farmers suffered losses after selling the rabi crop as well as the kharif crop, while tenants suffered more severely. Stung by the financial loss, farmers groups announced ‘a crop holiday’ as a protest in kharif season of 2011, putting up a string of demands. The major demands include: i) to raise the MSP to Rs. 2035 as per M S Swaminathan Committee recommendation; ii) to allow export of rice so that godowns of millers are cleared; iii) to integrate MGNREGS with agriculture; iv) to provide small scale mechanisation at 90 per cent subsidy; and iv) to provide a bonus of Rs.200. Responding to the call given by Konaseema Farming Protection Committee, farmers have volunatarily observed crop holiday in 9 mandals in 78,000 acres. Some analysts believe that the movement also reflected ire of landlords jointly towards labour (whose bargaining power has gone up in recent period) and at the same time at the tenants who are seeking formal identity as tenants (which can threaten the legal proprietary of ownership) and at the State (which has neglected the farming community in general). Government responded by appointing a Committee headed by Mohan Kanda, former Chief Secretary, IAS. Box: Mohan Kanda Committee Recommendations The Andhra Pradesh Government had constituted the Mohan Kanda committee, to study the ‘crop holiday’ declared by the farmers in Godavari districts. The committee made consultations with farmers, farmers organisations, officials of the State agricultural department and Civil Supplies Department. The Committee after deliberating on all related and relevant issues gave three sets of recommendations to the State Government: first as immediate measures, such as: State to undertake desilting and modernisation of irrigation channels, to work out a flexible MSP to cover the (increased) cost of cultivation and to speed up payment of insurance, to advance the crop cycle to avoid harvesting in the cyclone-prone months through mechanised transplanters and opening water in canals right in the first week of June. In the medium run, reduce cost of cultivation through mechanisation and rational use of inputs, to provide green manure at subsidy, to increase its share in procurement, to include drainage clearance and desilting under MGNREGS, and encourage early rabi cultivation, to increase the allocation of railway rakes up to 100 to East Godavari, to announce export policy during/before harvesting period but not later, and iii) to increase the storage space in the district. In the long run, to set up regulated market yards, to increase capacity building of farmers in marketing, to improve marketing intelligence to farmers, to consider shifting of cropping pattern to oil palm and others to ease excess supply, to set up a coir board for the district and help coconut cultivation in the State, to develop demand-driven information systems, and early-warning weather forecasting. State Government has accepted several of these in principle, to begin with has announced that 5.0 million tonnes of paddy will be lifted from the farmers, which is double than last year.
♣ R.V. Ramana Murthy (rvramana66@gmail.com) is an Associate Professor in the Department of Economics, University of Hyderabad. * Rekha Misra (rekhamisra@rbi.org.in) is a Director in the Department of Economic and Policy Research, Reserve Bank of India. 1 The major non-foodgrain crops are cotton, oilseeds, chilies, turmeric, onions and vegetables. 2 It is also important to consider weighted rainfall index. 4 These estimates are based on NSS rounds up to 2004-05. When the latest 66th Round NSS data of 2009-10 is considered, the per capita average consumption of rice has fallen drastically to 10.54 kg/month for rural and 8.98 kg/month for urban. According to the projections based on 66th Round of NSS, the demand has been lower by 7 million tonnes. When the requirements of new Food Security Bill are considered, it may still be around 10.52 million tonnes. Projections for the next five years in such case are not likely to be above 10.54 million tonnes. This is because of negative elasticity of consumption for income due to drop in per capital rice consumption (Table 3.1). Even after considering the substitution and income effects, the additional demand is not likely to be more than one million tonne. 5 Earlier FCI used to categorise rice into three types such as common, fine and superfine. Of late, fine and superfine are merged and are called Grade-A. For eg., Swarna variety is considered as Grade-A. But in the market it is considered lower than the superfine BPTs. 6 The CACP methodology may underestimate the actual costs on several counts. First, it does not consider actual wages, instead it adjusts base year labour costs using labor cost index estimated by the Labour Bureau, which may be lower than the actual wages prevailing in the market. Second, it takes official rent according to the tenancy legislations. Third, it assumes bank interest rates of priority sector, where as majority of farmers take credit from the informal sources of finance which charge a much higher rate of interest. 7 Owner-tenant is one who owns some land and also leases-in some land. 8 There are no village level markets yards so it is important to consider transportation costs. Farmers need to hire transport and they often cover a distance of 10-15 km which costs Rs.1500 for every 20 quintals. 9 Real wages are computed as nominal wages deflated by Consumer Price Index for Agricultural labourers. 10 There could be several explanations for the rise in rural wages such as growing education, increased rural-urban migration, resonance effect of rise in urban wages in construction industry, and ageing of traditional rural agricultural labour. 11 Tenant farmers get consumption and production loans from the commission agents with which they tend to increase their standard of living. Such credit is not available for agricultural labour. 12 This is also noted by several other scholars like Parthasarathy (1983, 2002), Vamsi et al (2011). 13 Levy order is issued by the State Governments under Essential Security and Maintenance of Commodities Act though with the prior concurrence of the Central Government. 14 The prevailing practice is that millers are expected to lift the major share and procurement agencies lift paddy only if the market price comes below the MSP. Being a grain deficit State for a long time, the procurement target has traditionally been fixed at a low level, and the millers usually lift most of the output. 15 The Government had appointed a Committee headed by former Chief Secretary, Mr. Mohan Kanda, to study the problems faced by farmers in ‘Crop Holiday’ affected mandals of East Godavari district [Appendix]. One of main recommendations is the need for increased procurement of paddy from the farmers. Government announced that it has accepted to raise its procurement target to 5.0 million tonnes. 16 The market price for superfine varieties normally was Rs.1200-1400 per quintal till 2008-09. |