RbiSearchHeader

Press escape key to go back

Past Searches

Theme
Theme
Text Size
Text Size
S2

RbiAnnouncementWeb

RBI Announcements
RBI Announcements

சொத்து வெளியீட்டாளர்

83762041

Sustainability of Services-Led Growth: An Input Output Analysis of the Indian Economy
(Part 1 of 3)

Sanjay K. Hansda*

The sustainability of services as also of services-led growth of the Indian economy has been addressed in terms of the inter-sectoral linkages as emanating from the input-output transactions tables for 1993-94 both at the disaggregated level of 115 activities and the aggregated level of 10 constructed national accounts categories. At the disaggregated level, the Indian economy is found to be predominantly services-intensive with 55 per cent activities direct services-intensive and industry the most services-intensive sector. In the process, industrial activities turn out to be the major pace setter for services-growth. On the other hand, services stand out to have the largest inducing effect on the economy as per the Rasmussen measure of both backward and forward linkages. The backward and forward coefficients of variation indices, however, show that the inducing impulses from services might have worked mainly through the channel of forward linkage. However, since the forward linkage is inherently less effective than the backward linkage, the inducing impact of services on the rest of the economy could be limited. Nevertheless, as per the index of vertical integration, the services sector is found to have the largest expansionary potential (multiplying effect) on the rest of the economy. Therefore, the services-led growth augurs well for the Indian economy for sustaining the overall GDP growth. However, since the multiplier value remains less than one for all the activities including services, the expansionary potential of a services-led growth may not be over emphasised unless accompanied by growth impulses from other sources.

JEL Classification: O14

Key words: Services, Input-Output Analysis

Introduction

The services sector has been the mainstay of the Indian growth process in the 1990s. While the share of services has been ruling high ever since independence, it has received a major fillip only in the 1990s. Indeed, contribution of the services sector to the overall GDP growth peaked an all time high of 65.1 per cent in the 1990s up from 43.6 per cent in the 1980s. As a result, the services share in GDP went up by a spectacular 7.9 per cent in a single decade of the 1990s touching the mark of 48.5 per cent in 2000-01 while the sector took about four decades to improve its share by 12.6 per cent to 40.6 per cent in 1990-91 from 28.0 per cent in 1950-51. The ascendancy of services has had a stabilising effect on the growth process itself. To quote from the Reserve Bank’s Report on Currency and Finance, 2000-01, ‘‘…it is the services sector which has kept the GDP growth around 6.0 per cent in the 1990s when industry and agriculture sectors did not perform relatively well’’ (p. iii – 44). Thus, ‘‘the services sector has been the most dynamic sector of the Indian economy, especially over the last ten years’’ (National Statistical Commission, 2001, art 7.1.2).1

Another notable feature of the 1990s is the emergence of information technology (IT) related services. On this count, India has come to be increasingly recognised as a post-industrial society and as a knowledge-based economy. Such optimism is possibly routed to the recent spurt in software exports and the perceived potential of trade in services such as IT, communications and entertainment. Indeed, in conjunction to the domestic economy, services, hitherto considered non-tradable, have provided a significant source of comfort to the country’s balance of payments in the 1990s. The Reserve Bank’s Report on Currency and Finance, 2000-01 has explicitly recognised this development: ‘‘As against a deficit of US $ 0.2 billion in 1990-91 that partly exacerbated the external payments imbalances during that year, the net invisible surplus has grown over time to around US $ 12-13 billion in the recent period, imparting resilience and sustainability to current account deficits and overall balance of payments during the 1990s’’ (p.vi -6).

The preponderance of services in the Indian economy, however, runs counter to the conventional wisdom on development at least on two counts (Madheswaran and Dharmadhikary, 2000). The well-known sequence of structural transformation from an agrarian economy to a predominantly service economy en route an industrial economy as noticed in the developed world has not been witnessed in India. While the share of agriculture in GDP has registered a secular decline from 57.7 per cent in 1950-51 to 24.2 per cent in 2000-01, the void has not been filled in by industry even though it has improved its share to 27.3 per cent in 2000-01 from 14.8 per cent in 1950-51. On the other hand, services sector has come to occupy the position of a prime mover in the Indian economy with its share at 48.5 per cent in 2000-01 as against 28.0 per cent in 1950-51. The observed dominance of services ahead of industry with the decline of agriculture has, however, given rise to apprehension as to whether the sequence of the growth process would be reversed in the future particularly when industry is yet to achieve adequate growth. Such apprehension seems to have gained a ground in the absence of preponderance of services in the country’s employment. In 1999-00, services have accounted for around 23.5 per cent of total employment in the country. On the other hand, agriculture still continues to account for a major share of employment despite its secular decline in terms of share in GDP. In the developed world, however, rise and dominance of a sector in GDP has been accompanied by its simultaneous ascendancy in employment. The observed counter-factuals in terms of sequence of growth and employment as also the apparent imbalance between the two have been an added concern in the Indian growth process.

The spectacular performance of the services sector in the 1990s has once again raked up the issue of its plausibility and sustainability (Acharya, 2002b). The issue has attracted an added attention in view of the fact that a part of the services growth is reckoned to be ‘spurious’ as reflecting the revaluation of contribution from public administration and defence in line with the Fifth Pay Commission’s recommendations. The impact of such wage hike on GDP has found place even in official documents including the Economic Survey, 1998-99: ‘‘…fully one percentage point of growth of 5.0 per cent in GDP for 1997-98 is attributed to the 20 per cent increase in real value added in the ‘public administration and defence’ sub-sector arising chiefly from pay increases to government servants’’ (p.1). Subsequent sobering of the growth performance of the economy seems to have extended credence to such concerns.

Indeed, the high growth momentum of the 1990s seems to have petered out in the new millennium with the growth fatigue finally catching up the services sector. The GDP growth crashed to an abysmal 4.0 per cent in 2000-01, the lowest since 1992-93, under the weight of the services growth touching the rock bottom of 4.8 per cent, a level witnessed only in the crisis year of 1991-92. Although a modicum of recovery set in during 2001-02 both for the services sector and the GDP, the sudden deceleration of the services sector has brought the question of its sustainability at the centre-stage.

Even in the financial press, the question being hotly debated has been: how long can the services growth remain immune to the happenings in agriculture and industry? For example, S. S. Anklesaria Iyer (2002a; 2002b) in a series of articles in The Economic Times has welcomed the rapid growth of services in the 1990s. In his view, ‘as the industry-less growth is here to stay, our ability to compensate for industrial failure with services success is a strength, not a weakness’. On the other hand, Acharya (2002a; 2002c) has been sceptical of the idea of services-led growth. In his words, ‘…India’s services sector can’t enjoy fast and sustained growth. It can, but only in tandem with a fast growing industrial sector…Services cannot, by themselves, assure rapid and sustained growth of the Indian economy.’

As the Indian economy is currently passing through a phase of industrial slowdown coupled with a cyclical downturn in agriculture, a perceptive view on the services growth assumes prescriptive importance in steering the economy on to the path of recovery. It is against this backdrop, the present study sets out its focus on the sustainability of services growth as also of the overall services-led growth process. Specifically, the study is built around the following quests: what is the services intensity of the various sectors of the economy? How strong are the backward and forward linkages of services with the rest of the sectors? Are the strong backward and forward linkages of services, if any, an outcome of large transactions with a few sectors or an outcome of broad-based transactions with many sectors? What is the expansionary potential of services on non-services in terms of the multiplying effect on the rest of the economy? Which services have the largest multiplier effect on the economy?

The rest of the study is organised as follows. Section I presents a select survey of literature on the role of services in the growth process with special reference to India. Section II offers a snapshot of the observed relationship between the services and the major macro aggregates including income, consumption, capital and export in the Indian economy. Section III discusses the methodological background and data sources. Section IV presents the empirical findings coupled with their possible interpretations. Section V concludes the study.

Section I

Services Sector and Economic Growth: A Select Survey of Literature

The role of services in the development process is marked by a long controversy. In fact, the debate dates back to Adam Smith who was of the view that services ‘perish in the very instant of their performance and seldom leave any trace or value behind them’. As such, services have drawn for themselves a tag of unproductive activity from the classical economists. Until recently, services used to be treated accordingly by the erstwhile socialist or centrally planned economies and classified as ‘non-material production’ as against the productive ‘material production’ in their national accounts statistics.

While services have long come out of such categorisation, the debate seems to have shifted its focus to the level of productivity. While Fisher (1935) and Clark (1940) attributed the preponderance of services in the developed world to its level of income, they recognised the low productivity in services as a factor behind the faster employment growth in services than in industry. Fuchs (1965) also came to a similar conclusion for the US economy in the 1960s. Such productivity differentials formed the basis of the well-known ‘cost disease’ hypothesis of services propounded by Baumol (1967). Higher productivity in industry was visualised to raise wages even in services more than the productivity growth, leading to a chronic tendency for costs and prices of services to increase relative to goods. In view of the post-1973 productivity slowdown in the US, increasing tertiarisation of the US economy has been a cause for concern (Triplett & Bosworth, 2000).

The reported low productivity in services has however been questioned, among others, by Griliches (1992). The low level of services productivity is advocated to be a fall-out of mis-measurement of services output. Besides, factors like technological change, deregulation and increased competition are set to raise productivity at least in select services (Maclean, 1996). Even Baumol et al (1985) have recognised the case of ‘progressive’ services with substantial productivity gains. Besides, the ‘asymptotically stagnant’ services initially register productivity gains followed by standardisation and stagnation in productivity. Nevertheless, there is now increasing recognition that the very act of service even involves externalities for user or the user’s goods in terms of gain in productivity or its potential (Hill, 1977). In fact, such over-bearing feature of services makes the estimation exercise daunting and more so for the newly arrived activity of information technology (IT)-related services as the national statistical systems are largely designed to capture developments only in the goods sector. This has led to a situation of low measured productivity despite increased use of computers and IT, which is otherwise expected to boost the productivity growth. This incongruity is popularly known as the Solow productivity paradox. While several attempts have been made to explain the paradox, the exact role of distortions in official statistics therein remains controversial (Diewert, et al, 1999).

Yet another popular scepticism perceives services as innovation laggards and primarily consumers of innovation in manufacturing (Miles, 1993). However, increasingly such a view has come to be questioned in recent period. In contrast to a manufacturing innovation in terms of new or improved product/process, innovation in services often relates to how, where and when a service is delivered (Howells, 2000). Productivity-enhancing investment in ICT (i.e., information and communication technology), regulatory reform and growing tradability of services are among the major factors contributing to innovations in services (Pilat, 2000a).

A logical corollary to the concerns of productivity and innovation has been the view that high growth, be that of services or the service-oriented economies, is not sustainable. The decline in manufacturing and the corresponding shift to services is widely held to be unsupportable in the long run since services depend critically on manufacturing for their existence. Such well-entrenched notion of parasitic and dependent services has recently come under increasing scrutiny (Bryson and Daniels, 1998). Rather than services following and supporting manufacturing, manufacturing is seen as flowing to those countries and areas where the services infrastructure is efficient and well developed (OECD, 2000). Besides, the increasing resembling of services with commodities has enabled the former to emerge as the major driving force in economic growth. Thus, the conclusion that service economies are naturally sluggish seems to be premature (US Department of Commerce, 1996).

Be that as it may, the growing role of services in national economies is clear and unequivocal particularly for the developed world, which could better be labelled as post-industrial society (Bell, 1967). A variety of explanations are put forward in the literature to explain such an orientation. To begin with, the building block of the Fisher-Clark hypothesis of increasing tertiarisation with increased income has been a variant of the Engel’s Law that the income elasticity of demand for services is greater than that of demand for goods. While early empirical works have found support to such hypothesis, recent studies such as Falvey and Gemmell (1996) have tended to reject the income-elastic demand for services overall but confirm a wide range of income elasticity estimates (above and below unity) across different types of services. Indeed, in contrast to a post-industrial society, Gershuny (1978) has even advocated a self-service economy, wherein self-service activities with the help of consumer durables are visualised to replace the purchased consumer services. The increased use of consumer durables is expected to enhance the demand for intermediate services such as servicing and repair of household equipments. The Gershuny effect is found to operate in a number of developed and developing economies including Brazil (Flores, 1995). The thesis has also been questioned both on theoretical and empirical grounds. For example, Silver (1987) has argued that increasing woman participation in workforce reduces the time available for self-service within the household. On the other hand, emergence of a broad-based prosperous middle class coupled with an ageing population is found to boost the demand for consumer services in the Asia (Wirtz, 2001).

The process towards increasing specialisation and vertical disintegration has entailed focusing on core competencies combined with outsourcing of peripheral activities (Stigler, 1956). The externalisation of non-core activities, formerly carried out in-house and counted as industrial output, is believed to be the engine of services growth and, by the same token, decline of industry. Such contracting out renders the firm’s cost structure flexible necessitated by a shorter product cycle and changing taste pattern. However, externalisation is found to have only marginally influenced the growth of small business service firms of the UK (Bryson, et al, 1993). Yet another accounting explanation of the services growth can be traced to the work of Browne (1986). With the increasing monetisation of the economy, a major chunk of household activities is outsourced from the market. The measured growth of national income is, therefore, biased upward since such shifts in production do not result in a corresponding increase in total output of the combined household and market sectors.

With the increasing complexities of modern industrial organisations, manufacturing activities have become more and more service intensive both upstream (e.g., design and R & D) and downstream (e.g., marketing and advertising) (Pilat, 2000b). Competitive advantage of a firm now depends more on providing specialised services like financing and after-sales facilities than on production, which has increasingly become routinised. On the other hand, new in-house services have come up to extend an interface with the outside provider of services on externalisation of the latter (UNCTAD, 1989, p. 145). All these are arguably reflected in increased demand for intermediate services. In the case of Canada, however, intermediate services have not registered substantial increase (Economic Council of Canada, 1991).

The ascendancy of services in the developed world has often been accompanied by deindustrialisation as in the case of the UK. Kaldor (1966) was of the view that a mature economy could continue to benefit from economies of scale ‘not through a fast growth in manufacturing industry as a whole, but through greater international specialism … or in other words by increasing the degree of interdependence of British industry with the industries of other countries’ (p. 122). Thus, management and service functions may be located in one country while manufacturing activities in another. Such a process has possibly worked out in rapid industrialisation of the developing world and de-industrialisation of the developed world.

In the Indian context, the increasing share of services in GDP has been a source of controversy ever since independence. Rao (1954) discounted it as an indicator of development in the context of a developing country. Nevertheless, the dominance of services was traced back to factors such as the increasing role of government in economic planning and execution, the historical role of urban middle class in wholesale trade and distribution, and the demonstration effect of high income countries (Panchamukhi, et al, 1986). The sustainability of a service-led growth was once again questioned by Shah (1987) and Mitra (1988). Bhattacharya and Mitra (1989; 1990) also felt that the service-led growth could have serious implications for inflation, income distribution and balance of payments since income (employment) might have grown faster than employment (income) in the organised (un-organised) services. Besides, ‘…income from service sector is growing much in excess of the demand generated for the services by the commodity sector’ (p. 2449). However, in view of the similar pattern of growth both in net material product and NDP during 1950-51 to 1983-84, Datta (1989) refuted the view of overgrowth of the services sector. Given the limited role of services in employment generation and absorption, policy intervention was advocated in some circles (Mazumdar, 1995, and Arunachalam and Kumar, 2002). Bhowmik (2000) highlighted the fact that about 50 per cent industries in the Indian economy were direct and direct plus indirect services intensive in 1991-92. Besides, services appeared to be the most growth-inducing and generated a higher value added in other industries than in their own.

Section II

Services Sector in the Indian Growth Process: A Few Stylized Facts

The preponderance of services over industry is not a recent phenomenon for the Indian economy but has been in place since the beginning of 1950s (Table 1). Such predominance of services over industry could be an outcome of the de-industrialisation process pursued in British India (Bagchi, 1982). While the decline of the primary sector, i.e., largely agriculture, is in keeping with the conventional wisdom on development, the preponderance of services ahead of industry stands out as a departure from the past. Nonetheless, the Indian experience is not a standalone case. A number of developing countries such as Zambia, Chad, Sudan, Kenya and Pakistan have also undergone a similar phase in their development process.


                    

Table 1: Agriculture, Industry and Services: Shares in GDP

     

(Per cent)


Year

Agriculture

Industry

Services


1

2

3

4


1950-51

57.2

14.8

28.0

1960-61

54.7

16.6

28.7

1970-71

48.1

19.9

32.1

1980-81

41.8

21.6

36.6

1990-91

34.9

24.5

40.6

2000-01

24.2

27.3

48.5

2001-02

24.3

26.7

49.0


Source: Central Statistical Organisation.

Moreover, the decline in growth of GDP has in general not been accompanied by a reduction in share of services (Table 2). This observation runs counter to the established theories but is in keeping with the growth experience of the developed world (Chandrasekhar and Ghosh, 2000). The visible hand of the government as reflected in planning and production in the economy as a whole could have contributed to such a development (Mazumdar, 1995).

Table 2: Services and GDP: Growth and Share

     

(Per cent)


Year

Services

GDP

Services

 

Growth

Growth

Share


1

2

3

4


1951-52

2.7

2.3

28.1

1960-61

5.9

7.1

28.7

1970-71

4.9

5.0

32.1

1980-81

4.5

7.2

36.6

1990-91

5.3

5.6

40.6

2000-01

4.8

4.0

48.5

2001-02

6.5

5.4

49.0


Source: Central Statistical Organisation.

The services sector entered the decade of 1990s with a growth of 5.3 per cent, even lower than the GDP growth of 5.6 per cent in 1990-91 (Table 3). In the following year of the balance of payments crisis when both agriculture and industry encountered a negative growth, services posted a positive growth of 4.8 per cent, ensuring an overall GDP growth of 1.3 per cent. During the boom phase of 7 per cent plus GDP growth, i.e., from 1994-95 to 1996-97, the growth in services as well ruled over 7 per cent. In the subsequent years till 2001-02, the services growth remained higher than those of the other sectors barring 2000-01 when it crashed to a mere 4.8 per cent primarily gravitated by the negative growth in non-bank financial companies. Overall, the services sector posted a growth of 7.6 per cent in 1990s up from 6.6 per cent in 1980s.

As per the Economic Survey, 2000-01, liberalisation of the economy in the 1990s and encouragement of private investment in industry and infrastructure have induced sustained high growth in services sector. A rapid increase in expenditure on public administration and defence, social services, and rural extension services also has an impact on the growth of services sector. Besides, IT software and services has emerged as one of the fastest growing segments of the economy with a compound annual growth of over 50 per cent during 1990s (Rastogi, 2002).

Table 3: Sectoral and Overall GDP Growth Since 1990-91

       

(Per cent)


Year

Agriculture

Industry

Services

GDP


1

2

3

4

5


1990-91

4.1

7.7

5.3

5.6

1991-92

-0.02

-0.6

4.8

1.3

1992-93

5.8

4.0

5.4

5.1

1993-94

4.1

5.2

7.7

5.9

1994-95

5.0

10.2

7.1

7.3

1995-96

-0.9

11.6

10.5

7.3

1996-97

9.6

7.1

7.2

7.8

1997-98

-2.4

4.3

9.8

4.8

1998-99

6.2

3.4

8.3

6.5

1999-00

1.3

5.3

9.5

6.1

2000-01

-0.2

6.3

4.8

4.0

2001-02

5.7

3.3

6.5

5.4


Memo Item

       

1990-00

3.3

5.8

7.6

5.8

1980-90

4.4

6.8

6.6

5.8


Source: Central Statistical Organisation.

   

In commensurate with the value added, services share in private final consumption expenditure has witnessed a steady increase from 10.2 per cent in 1950-51 to 29.0 per cent in 2000-01 (Hansda, 2002). The share of services export as a per cent of merchandise export has also improved from 13.8 per cent in 1950-51 to 45.1 per cent in 2001-02. On the other hand, the share of services in net fixed capital stock has declined from as high as 68.4 per cent in 1950-51 to 45.3 per cent in 1999-00. Similar trend is observed in its share of gross capital formation (i.e., investment), which has decreased from 57.7 per cent in 1950-51 to 39.6 per cent in 1999-2000. The absorption of labour in services has also not been that encouraging.

While the various sources of growth vent out conflicting signal for services, the sector has come to occupy the dominant position in the Indian economy by the end of 1990s. Probably greater intersectoral linkages as reflected in the growing intermediate use of services as against their final use have been the major contributor to the services growth (Table 4). The intermediate use of services output has grown from 31.2 per cent in 1968-69 to 38.5 per cent in 1993-94 when its final use has declined from 68.8 per cent to 61.5 per cent over the same period. The increased intermediate use of services output has taken place in the production of both commodities and services. It is towards such exploration of intersectoral linkages, the following section discusses the methodology of the present study.

Table 4: Percentage Distribution of Services Output


Item

Year

Commo-

Services

Intermediate

Final

Total

   

dities

 

Use

Use

Output


1

2

3

4

5

6

7


Services

1968-69

21.8

9.4

31.2

68.8

100.0

 

1973-74

21.2

9.4

30.6

69.4

100.0

 

1978-79

23.4

15.5

38.9

61.1

100.0

 

1983-84

24.4

13.1

37.5

62.5

100.0

 

1989-90

27.8

12.8

40.6

59.4

100.0

 

1993-94

26.8

11.7

38.5

61.5

100.0


Source: Input-Output Transactions Table 1993-94, CSO (2000).

 

Section III

Data Base and Methodology

Given the line of inquiry as set out ab initio, the empirical quest has been pursued in an input-output framework. For the purpose, CSO’s latest Input-Output Transactions Table (IOTT), which pertains to the year 1993-94, has been utilised. As per the IOTT, 1993-94, the economy is disaggregated into 115 activities, of which 22 activities are in agriculture, 80 in industry and 13 in services. The analysis is carried out both at the level of 115 activities and at the aggregated level. For the later, 115 activities are clubbed into 10 broad categories in line with the sectorisation of national accounts statistics.

The widely used measures of inter-sectoral dependence are the backward, forward and total linkage indices a la Rasmussen (1956). Backward linkage of a sector measures the inducement to production in other sectors, which is absorbed as an input to the former. On the other hand, forward linkage of a sector measures the extent to which the sector provides inputs for utilisation by other sectors. The sectors having large total linkage is called the key sectors for the purpose of investment allocation with a view to ensuring a faster industrialisation.

The Rasmussen measures of inter-sectoral linkages have been criticised in the literature on a number of grounds. The backward and forward linkages are even shown to be mutually inconsistent, among others, by Cella (1984). Against such a backdrop, Heimler (1991) has put forward an alternative index of vertical integration, which measures the multiplying effect of each activity on the gross output of the rest of the economy.

where TVAs stands for total value added of services. The index Int measures the indirect effect of services on non-services and, in turn, on services, providing a dimension free measure of the multiplier of each on the value added of the rest of the economy. The activity for which Int is the highest can be ranked as the key sector of the economy in terms of its ability to generate value added in other activities.

Section IV

Empirical Findings

Sectoral Intensity

The sectoral intensity of activities provides a ready-reckoner of the inter-sectoral linkages between agriculture, industry and services. While the details on sectoral intensity for all the 115 activities are presented in Appendix Table 1, Table 5 reports the summary observations. As per the direct measure of intensity (G), 34 out of 115 activities or 30 per cent activities have had the agricultural intensity above the average of 7 per cent of gross output. The sector of agriculture itself has turned out to be the most agriculture-intensive sector with 68 per cent of agricultural activities having the agriculture intensity above the average as against 23 per cent and 8 per cent of industrial and services activities respectively. Only one out of 13 services activities, viz., hotels and restaurants has the agricultural intensity above the average. This implies that services activities hardly draw their inputs from agriculture while such linkage is relatively strong between industry and agriculture. In terms of variation in intensities, range in agricultural intensity has been higher than that of services intensity but less than that of industrial intensity. The picture has remained more or less the same in terms of the direct and indirect measure of intensity (G*).

Table 5: Distribution of Activities with Above Average Sectoral Intensity

           

(No. of Activities)


Item

Agriculture

Industry

Services

   

Intensive

Intensive

Intensive


   

G

G*

G

G*

G

G*


 

1

2

3

4

5

6

7


1.

Agricultural

15

15

0

0

1

1

 

Activity

(68)

(68)

(0)

(0)

(5)

(5)

2.

Industrial

18

22

57

55

56

59

 

Activity

(23)

(28)

(71)

(69)

(70)

(74)

3.

Services

1

1

3

3

6

2

 

Activity

(8)

(8)

(23)

(23)

(46)

(15)

4.

Total

34

38

60

58

63

62

 

(1+2+3)

(30)

(33)

(52)

(50)

(55)

(54)


Memo Items#

           

Average

7

12

29

59

15

30

Intensity

           

Minimum to

0 to

0 to

0 to

-14 to

0 to

0 to

Maximum

74

88

76

154

41

68

Intensity Range

           

Figures in bracket are percentage share in the respective sectoral total of activities. G: Direct intensity; G*: Direct plus indirect intensity; #: As percent to gross output.

In terms of the direct measure of intensity (G), 60 out of 115 activities or 52 per cent activities have reported higher than the average industrial intensity of 29 per cent of gross output. Notably, not a single agricultural activity has the above average industrial intensity. The industrial sector with 57 out of 80 industrial activities or 71 per cent of its activities has been the most industry intensive when only 3 services activities out of 13, viz., medical and health, railway transport services, and other transport services, have the above average industry intensity. In other words, neither agricultural nor services activities seem to be much dependent on industry for input. However, the industrial intensity of the economy stands out to be of high order with 50 per cent of the total number of activities displaying the above average industrial intensity even in terms of the direct and indirect measure of intensity (G*). The extent of variation in industrial intensity has been the most, possibly reflecting wide variation in technology at the activity level. Besides, the industrial intensity has turned out even negative for the activity of rubber production while the same has been more than 100 per cent for 17 industrial activities in terms of the direct and indirect measure of intensity (G*).

With 63 out of 115 activities or 55 per cent activities having the above average services intensity, the predominance of services intensive activities is clear in the economy. Interestingly, unlike agriculture and industry, services sector per se is not the most services intensive sector. It is the industrial sector, which has turned out to be relatively services intensive in its 56 out of 80 industrial activities (i.e., 70 per cent industrial activities). On the other hand, 6 out of 13 services activities, i.e., 46 per cent services activities have had the services intensity above the average of 15 per cent of gross output. Only one agricultural activity, viz., animal services (agricultural) has the above average services intensity. As per the direct and indirect measure of services intensity (G*), the number of industrial activities with the above average services intensity has gone up to 59 (i.e., 74 per cent of industrial activities) while that of services activities has declined to 2 with the overall number of activities down to 62 from 63. The average services intensity has also doubled to 30 per cent of gross output while the upper limit of variation in services intensity has increased to 68 per cent of gross output for ships and boats from 41 per cent for office computing machines. Three industrial activities, viz., office computing machines, ships and boats, and coal tar products stand out the most services intensive in terms of both direct, and direct and indirect measures of services intensity. On the other hand, public administration and ownership of dwellings have the lowest services intensity under both the definitions of services intensity. The average level of services intensity has been higher than that of agricultural intensity but stands lower than that of industrial intensity. The range of variation in services intensity turns out to be the lowest among all types of sectoral intensity. On the whole, the majority of activities and more so of the industrial activities turn out to be relatively services-intensive in the Indian economy.

At the aggregate level of 10 categories, three categories, viz., allied activities, agriculture and manufacturing, in terms of direct measure, and four categories, viz., the former three and construction, in terms of direct and indirect measure of intensity, have turned out to be relatively agriculture-intensive (Table 6). None of the aggregate categories of services are agriculture-intensive. Similarly for the industrial intensity, three industrial categories, viz., electricity, gas & water supply; manufacturing and construction, and one services category, viz., transport, storage and communication have had the industrial intensity above the average both in terms of direct, and direct and indirect measures of industrial intensity. Both the agricultural categories - agriculture and allied activities – are found to be not industry-intensive. On the other hand, industry has turned out to be more services-intensive than services. Three industrial categories out of four, viz., manufacturing, construction, and electricity, gas and water supply, and two services categories out of four, viz., transport, storage & communication, and trade, hotels & restaurants are found to be services-intensive in terms of direct measure of intensity. In terms of direct and indirect measure however, only one services category - transport, storage & communication – has the services intensity above the average. No agricultural category has been services-intensive. Thus, in keeping with the activity-wise trend, services and industry are found, at the aggregate level, more inter-dependent than services and agricultural sectors. Nonetheless, dominance of the services sector is clear even at the aggregate level.

Backward and Forward Linkages

As per the Rasmussen index of backward linkage accounting for both direct and indirect linkages, 46 out of the total of 115 activities (i.e., 40 per cent) – seven out of 22 agricultural activities (i.e., 32 per cent), 31 out of 80 industrial activities (i.e., 39 per cent) and eight out of 13 services activities (i.e., 62 per cent) –have had relatively large index value (Appendix Table 2). Clearly, the services activities have the largest inducing effect on the rest in terms of backward linkage. Activity-wise, construction from industry, trade and other transport services from services, and animal services (agricultural) and other crops from agriculture have had large backward index value in that order. The index value of backward linkage has varied between –0.23 for crude petroleum & natural gas and 4.59 for construction.

Similarly, in terms of the index of forward linkage, 15 out of the total of 115 activities (i.e., 13 per cent) – 5 out of 22 agricultural activities (i.e., 23 per cent), 3 out of 80 industrial activities (i.e., 4 per cent) and 7 out of 13 services activities (i.e., 54 per cent) –have reported high forward linkage index. Once again, the services activities are endowed with relatively large forward linkage. Activity-wise, forward linkage effects of trade and other transport services from services, other crops from agriculture, construction from industry and other services from services have been relatively high in that order. The index value of forward linkage has varied between -2.43 for crude petroleum & natural gas and 37.95 for trade.

Even in terms of the total of backward and forward linkage indices, a larger proportion of activities in services (69 per cent) than in industry (8 per cent) or agriculture (27 per cent) stand out to be the key sectors of the economy with the total index value higher than two. The top five activities in terms of the total index value are trade and other transport services from services, construction from industry, other crops from agriculture, and other services from services. Clearly, the first four activities are the ones having high backward as well as forward linkage. In total, 21 out of 115 activities (i.e., 18 per cent) can be termed as the key sectors of the economy with the total index value greater than two.

At the aggregate level, manufacturing, construction, agriculture, personal, social & other services; and transport, storage & communication are the key sectors in terms of the backward linkage (Table 7). On the other hand, only manufacturing and agriculture are the key sectors of the economy in terms of the forward linkage. Clearly, the high linkage of services at the activity level seems to have been overshadowed by aggregation.

Table 6: Sectoral Intensity – Aggregate Categories


Sector

Ga

Rank

G*a

Rank

Gi

Rank

G*i

Rank

Gs

Rank

G*s

    Rank


1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13


Agriculture

0.131

2

0.172

3

0.092

7

0.211

8

0.057

10

0.122

8

Allied activities

0.179

1

0.220

1

0.039

10

0.127

9

0.068

8

0.121

9

Mining & quarrying

0.000

9

0.028

9

0.190

5

0.358

5

0.070

7

0.152

7

Manufacturing

0.091

3

0.179

2

0.420

2

0.811

1

0.185

2

0.385

1

Construction

0.024

5

0.095

4

0.362

3

0.706

3

0.202

1

0.381

2

Electricity, gas &

0.004

8

0.038

8

0.453

1

0.800

2

0.166

4

0.330

3

water supply

                       

Transport, storage

0.023

6

0.074

5

0.282

4

0.560

4

0.175

3

0.317

4

& communication

                       

Trade, hotels &

0.034

4

0.060

6

0.091

8

0.214

7

0.160

5

0.227

5

restaurants

                       

Financing, insurance

0.000

10

0.006

10

0.044

9

0.089

10

0.061

9

0.087

10

& real estate

                       

Personal, social &

0.016

7

0.048

7

0.152

6

0.301

6

0.090

6

0.167

6

other services

                       

Average Intensity

0.050

 

0.092

 

0.212

 

0.418

 

0.123

 

0.229

 

G: Direct sectoral intensity; G*: Direct and indirect sectoral intensity; a: agriculture; i: industry; s: services.

Table 7: Backward & Forward Linkage Indices – Aggregate Categories


 

Sector

B. Index

Rank

F. Index

Rank


 

1

2

3

4

5


1

Agriculture

1.26

3

1.54

2

2

Allied activities

0.81

7

0.53

7

3

Mining & quarrying

0.26

10

-0.18

10

4

Manufacturing

2.24

1

4.32

1

5

Construction

1.46

2

0.67

5

6

Electricity, gas & water supply

0.48

8

0.07

9

7

Transport, storage & communication

1.03

5

0.64

6

8

Trade, hotels & restaurants

0.90

6

0.98

3

9

Financing, insurance & real estate

0.45

9

0.50

8

10

Personal, social & other services

1.11

4

0.92

4


Average Index

1

 

1

 

B: Backward Linkage; F: Forward Linkage.

     

Dispersal of Backward and Forward Linkages

In order to take into account the variation in the index of linkage, both the backward and forward coefficient of variation indices have been calculated (Appendix Table 3). A relatively large value of such indices implies that a sector purchases (sells) inputs only from (to) a few sectors in the economy. As per the backward coefficient of variation index, 5 out of 13 services activities (i.e., 38 per cent), 45 out of 80 industrial activities (i.e., 56 per cent) and 12 out of 22 agricultural activities (i.e., 55 per cent) have their index value below the average of 5.50 per cent. The low proportion of services activities with low backward coefficient of variation in contrast to the high proportion of services activities with high backward linkage implies that the strong backward linkage of the majority of services owes to the large inter-sectoral purchases from only a few sectors rather than widespread purchases from many different activities. Notably, all the five top performers in terms of the backward linkage index have as well a high backward coefficient of variation index.

However, in terms of the forward coefficient of variation index, seven out of 13 services activities (i.e., 54 per cent) as against 27 out of 80 industrial activities (i.e, 34 per cent) and eight out of 22 agricultural activities (i.e., 36 per cent) have the index value below the average of 6.91 per cent. Thus, high proportion of services activities with high forward linkage is also accompanied by high proportion of services activities with low forward coefficient of variation. In other words, the strong forward linkage of the majority of services owes to the widespread sale to many different activities. Interestingly, the five top performers in terms of the forward linkage have also a low forward coefficient of variation. Thus, the inducing impulses from the services sector appear to have worked mainly through the channel of forward linkage with the rest of the economy.

At the aggregate level, mining & quarrying, manufacturing; transport, storage & communication; agriculture; trade, hotels & restaurants, and personal, social & other services have low backward coefficient of variation (Table 8). Therefore, the sectors identified with high backward linkage seem to be purchasing inputs from a wide spectrum of sectors as reflected in the low backward coefficient of variation. Construction turns out to be the only exception. The majority of services sectors have a low backward coefficient of variation at the aggregate level in contrast to the trend obtained at the activity level. On the other hand, transport, storage & communication; electricity, gas & water supply; construction, allied activities, trade, hotels & restaurants; personal, social & other services have low forward coefficient of variation index. In other words, the sectors with high forward linkage are found to have high forward coefficient of variation index, i.e., selling inputs to only a few sectors. Thus, the trend at the aggregate level differs from the activity level both in terms of linkage index and coefficient of variation index.

Table 8: Backward & Forward Coefficient of Variation Indices: Aggregate Categories


 

Sector

Viw

Rank

Vjw

Rank


 

1

2

3

4

5


1

Agriculture

1.85

4

2.35

8

2

Allied activities

3.13

8

1.68

4

3

Mining & quarrying

-4.71

1

3.47

10

4

Manufacturing

1.09

2

2.53

9

5

Construction

2.64

7

1.59

3

6

Electricity, gas & water supply

10.42

10

1.57

2

7

Transport, storage & communication

1.76

3

1.55

1

8

Trade, hotels & restaurants

1.88

5

1.93

5

9

Financing, insurance & real estate

3.40

9

2.34

7

10

Personal, social & other services

2.32

6

1.99

6


 

Average Index

2.38

 

2.10

 

Viw and Vjw are respectively the forward and the backward coefficient of variation indices.

Vertical Integration

In order to provide a dimension-free measure of the multiplier of each sector on the value added of the rest of the economy, the index of vertical integration has been calculated activity-wise (Appendix Table 3). 14 out of the 115 activities having the index value higher than the average are reported in Table 9. Out of the 14 activities, 7 activities belong to services, followed by 6 from industry and 1 from agriculture. The top 3 activities in terms of the index value turn out to be trade, banking and other transport services, all belonging to the services sector. Indeed, out of the total of 13 services activities, as many as 7 have large multiplier effect on the rest of the economy. On the other hand, out of the total of 80 industrial activities, only 6 provide a strong stimulus on the rest of the economy whereas only one activity out of the total of 22 agricultural activities, viz., other crops, does so. Clearly, services sector stands out to be more growth inducing than industry or agriculture. However, the multiplier value remains less than one for all the 115 activities, implying that the value added indirectly induced is less than the direct value added by each. Further, the activities – animal services (agricultural) from agriculture, mica from industry, and ownership of dwellings and public administration from services – appear to have no inducing effect on the rest of the economy. Only one activity – plastic products from industry – indicates a possible negative impact. Notably, the top five performers in terms of the total of backward and forward linkages, viz., trade, other transport services and other services from the services sector, construction from industry, and other crops from agriculture are also found to have relatively high stimulus for the rest of the economy in terms of the index of vertical integration.

Table 9: Activities with Index of Vertical Integration Above the Average

Activity

Index

Sector

Rank

1

2

3

4

Trade

0.118427

Services

1

Banking

0.053505

Services

2

Other transport services

0.046273

Services

3

Crude petroleum, natural gas

0.026344

Industry

4

Other services

0.023001

Services

5

Electricity

0.018460

Industry

6

Railway transport services

0.016679

Services

7

Other crops

0.014095

Agriculture

8

Communication

0.011990

Services

9

Insurance

0.011414

Services

10

Construction

0.010982

Industry

11

Coal & lignite

0.008537

Industry

12

Miscellaneous manufacturing

0.007211

Industry

13

Drugs & medicines

0.004917

Industry

14

Average Index

0.003878

   

At the aggregate level of 10 categories, three categories from services, viz., trade, hotels & restaurants; transport, storage & communication; and financing, insurance & real estate, and one category from industry, viz., manufacturing have the index value above the average, indicating a clear dominance of services in terms of the multiplying effect on the rest of the economy vis-à-vis industry or agriculture (Table 10). In contrast to the position at the activity level, the stimulus of construction on the rest of the economy turns out the smallest at the aggregate level. Interestingly, manufacturing has been the single common category in terms of the backward/forward linkages as well as the index of vertical integration.

Table 10: Index of Vertical Integration – Aggregate Categories

 

Sector

Index

Rank

 

1

2

3

1

Agriculture

0.034825

5

2

Allied activities

0.012048

9

3

Mining & quarrying

0.023378

7

4

Manufacturing

0.062276

4

5

Construction

0.010932

10

6

Electricity, gas & water supply

0.020909

8

7

Transport, storage & communication

0.073804

2

8

Trade, hotels & restaurants

0.113444

1

9

Financing, insurance & real estate

0.063660

3

10

Personal, social & other services

0.032675

6

 

Average Index

0.044795

 

Section V

Concluding Observations

The growth of services as also the services-led growth of the Indian economy has been addressed in the study from the angle of sustainability. For the purpose, the study has primarily focused upon the inter-sectoral linkages as emanating from the input-output transactions tables for 1993-94 both at the aggregated level of 10 constructed national accounts categories and the most disaggregated level of 115 activities. While the aggregative analysis presents a variation from the disaggregated one, the Indian economy is found to be predominantly services-intensive at the disaggregated level with 55 per cent (54 per cent) activities direct (direct and indirect) services-intensive. The average services intensity stands doubled to 30 per cent of gross output with the switchover to direct and indirect services-intensity from direct services-intensity. The range of variation in services-intensity turns out the lowest among the three types of sectoral intensity defined in the study. While services and agriculture do not seem to share much inter-dependence, industry is observed to be the most services-intensive with 70 per cent (74 per cent) of its activities being direct (direct and indirect) services-intensive. While 46 per cent (15 per cent) of services activities stand out services-intensive, 23 per cent (23 per cent) of services activities report industry-intensive. Thus, while the industrial activities seem to be predominantly permeated with the services content, by the same token, they turn out to be the major pace setter for services-growth. In other words, sustained services-growth requires a growing industry too.

The inter-sectoral linkages are explored further in terms of the popular Rasmussen indices of backward and forward linkages as also their variation. Once again, 62 per cent (54 per cent) of services activities as against 39 per cent (4 per cent) of industrial activities and 32 per cent (23 per cent) of agricultural activities report strong inducing effect on the economy in terms of the backward (forward) linkage. The top 5 key sectors in terms of the total of backward and forward linkage indices turn out to be trade, other transport services and other services, construction and other crops. The strong backward linkage of services is found to be attributable to the large inter-sectoral purchases from only a few sectors. In contrast, the strong forward linkage of services is accompanied by widespread sales to many different activities. Thus, the inducing impulses from services might have worked mainly through the channel of forward linkage. However, since the forward linkage is inherently less effective than the backward linkage, the inducing impact of services on the rest of the economy could be limited.

Finally, the expansionary potential of services on non-services and services, in turn, has been examined by computing the index of vertical integration, which provides a dimension-free measure of the multiplier of each activity on the value added of the rest of the economy. Seven, six and one respectively out of 13 services, 80 industrial and 22 agricultural activities are found to have the largest expansionary potential. The top three activities in terms of the index value turn out to be trade, banking and other transport services, all belonging to the services sector. Further, the top five performers in terms of the total of backward and forward linkages are also found to have a relatively high index value of vertical integration. Clearly, the services sector stands out more growth inducing than industry or agriculture. Therefore, for sustaining the overall growth process, the services-led growth augurs well for the Indian economy in so far as the growth impulses originate in services vis-à-vis industry or agriculture. However, since the value added indirectly induced on the rest of the economy falls short of the direct value added by each activity including from services, the expansionary potential of services-led growth may not be over-emphasised unless accompanied by growth impulses from other sources.

Notes:

1Contrary to the popular view, Nagaraj (2000) however holds that ‘‘since the secondary sector growth rate has modestly slowed, the tertiary sector has become the fastest growing sector in the 1990s – but not because its growth rate has improved in that decade, statistically significantly’’ (p 2833).

References

Acharya, S. (2002a), ‘Growth Prospects Dim’, The Economic Times, January 3.

– (2002b), ‘Macroeconomic Management in the Nineties’, Economic and Political Weekly, 37 (16), April 20, 1515-1538.

– (2002c), ‘Services Not the Real Saviour’, The Economic Times, September 9.

Aiyar, S. S. Anklesaria (2002a), ‘Stuck in the 5-6 Per Cent Groove’, The Economic Times, August 7.

– (2002b), ‘Is Industryless Growth Here to Stay?’, The Economic Times, August 21.

Anjaneyulu, D. and Prakash, Ajay (1994), ‘Inter-Temporal Comparison of Inter-Industrial Linkages in the Indian Economy (1968-69 to 1983-84)’, Reserve Bank of India Occasional Papers, 15 (1), March, 1-30.

Arunachalam, R. and Kumar, K. N. (2002), ‘Dynamics of Services Sector in India: An Overview’, 1-12, in Gandhi, P. J. and Ganesan, P. (ed.) (2002),

Services Sector in the Indian Economy, Deep and Deep Publications Private Ltd., New Delhi.

Bagchi, A. K. (1982), The Political Economy of Underdevelopment, Cambridge.

Baumol, W. J. (1967), ‘Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: the Anatomy of an Urban Crisis’, American Economic Review, 57, 415-426, June.

Baumol, W. J., Blackman, S. A. B., and Wolff, E. N. (1985), ‘Unbalanced Growth Revisited: Asymptotic Stagnancy and the New Evidence’, American Economic Review, 75, September.

Bell, D. (1967), ‘Notes on the Post-Industrial Society (I)’, Public Interest, 6, Winter, 24-35.

Bhattacharya, B. B. and Mitra, A. (1989), ‘Industry-Agriculture Growth Rates: Widening Disparity: An Explanation’, Economic and Political Weekly, August 26.

– (1990), ‘Excess Growth of Tertiary Sector in Indian Economy: Issues and Implications’, Economic and Political Weekly, November 3, 2445-2450.

Bhowmik, R. (2000), ‘Role of Services Sector in Indian Economy: An Input-Output Approach’, Artha Vijnana, XLII (2), June, 158-169.

Browne, L. E. (1986), ‘Taking in Each Other’s Laundry – The Service Economy’, The New England Economic Review, July/August.

Bryson, J. R. and Daniels, P. W. (1998), ‘Introduction: Understanding the Rise and Role of Service Activities and Employment in the Global Economy: An Introduction to the Academic Literature’, in Bryson, J. R. and Daniels, P. W. (edited) (1998), Service Industries in the Global Economy, vol. I, Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd: Cheltenham, UK.

Bryson, J. R., Keeble, D., and Wood, P. (1993), ‘The Creation, Location and Growth of Small Business Service Firms in the United Kingdom’, Service Industries Journal, 13 (2), 118-131.

Cella, G. (1984), ‘The Input-Output Measurement of Inter-industry Linkages’, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 46, February, 73-84.

Central Statistical Organisation (2000), Input-Output Transactions Table 1993-94, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation, Government of India, New Delhi.

Chandrasekhar, C. P. and J. Ghosh (2000), ‘Services Sector Growth: What does it mean?’, Hindu Business Line.

Clark, C. (1940), The Conditions of Economic Progress, London: Macmillan.

Claus, Iris (2002), ‘Inter Industry Linkages in New Zealand’, Working Paper 02/09, June, New Zealand Treasury.

Datta, M. (1989), ‘Tertiary Sector and Net Material Product: Indian Economy, 1950-51 to 1983-84’, Economic and Political Weekly, September 23.

Diewert, E. W., Nakamura, A. and Sharpe, A. (ed.) (1999), ‘Special Issue on Service Sector Productivity and the Productivity Paradox’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 32 (2), April.

Economic Council of Canada (1991), Employment in the Service Sector, Ministry of Supply and Services, Ottawa, Canada.

Falvey, R. and Gemmell, N. (1996), ‘Are Services Income-Elastic? Some New Evidence’, Review of Income and Wealth, 42 (3), September.

Fisher, A. G. B. (1935), The Clash of Progress and Security, London: Macmillan.

Flores, R. G. Jr. (1995), ‘Three Hypotheses on the Brazilian Service Sector’, Review of Income and Wealth, 41 (2), June.

Fuchs, V. R. (1965), ‘The Growing Importance of the Service Industries’, Journal of Business, 38, 344-373.

Gershuny, J. (1978), After Industrial Society: The Emerging Self-Service Economy?,London: Macmillan.

Griliches, Z. (ed.) (1992), Output Measurement in the Service Sectors, National Bureau of Economic Research, Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 56, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Hansda, Sanjay K. (2002), ‘Services Sector in the Indian Economy: A Status Report’, RBI Staff Studies, S. S. (DEAP): 1/2002, September, Mumbai.

Heimler, A. (1991), ‘Linkages and Vertical Integration in the Chinese Economy’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 73, May, 261-267.

Hill, T. P. (1977), ‘On Goods and Services’, Review of Income and Wealth, 23 (4), 315-338, December.

Howells, J. (2000), ‘The Nature of Innovation in Services’, Report Presented to the OECD/Australia Workshop on Innovation and Productivity in Services, 31 October – 3 November, Sydney, Australia.

Kaldor, N. (1966), Causes for the Slow Rate of Growth of the United Kingdom, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Maclean, D. (1996), ‘Productivity Growth in the Commercial Service Sector’, Bank of Canada Review, autumn.

Madheswaran, S. and Dharmadhikary, A. (2000), ‘Income and Employment Growth in Service Sector in India’, The Indian Journal of Labour Economics, 43 (4), 835-864.

Mazumdar, Krishna (1995), ‘Disproportional Growth of Service Sector in India: 1960-1990’, The Indian Economic Journal, 43 (2), October-December.

Miles, I. (1993), ‘Services in the New Industrial Economy’, Futures, 25, 653-672.

Mitra, Ashok (1988), ‘Disproportionality and the Services Sector: A Note’, Social Scientist, April, 3-8.

Nagaraj, R. (2000), ‘Indian Economy since 1980: Virtuous Growth or Polarisation?’, Economic and Political Weekly, August 5, 2831-2838.

OECD (2000), A Report on Business & Industry Policy Forum, Paris.

Panchamukhi, V. R., Nambiar, R. G. and Mehta, R. (1986), ‘Structural Change and Economic Growth in Developing Countries’, VIII Work Economic Congress of International Economic Association, December.

Pilat, D. (2000a), ‘Innovation and Productivity in Services: State of the Art’, Paper Prepared for the OECD/Australia Workshop on Innovation and Productivity in Services, 31 October – 3 November, Sydney, Australia.

– (2000b), ‘No Longer Services As Usual’, OECD Observer, November 23.

Proops, J. L. R. (1988), ‘Energy Intensities, Input-Output Analysis and Economic Development’, in Ciaschini, M. (edited), Input-Output Analysis, London: Chapman and Hall Ltd.

Rao, V. K. R. V. (1954), ‘Changes in India’s National Income – A Static Economy in Progress’, Capital, December 16.

Rasmussen, P. N. (1956), Studies in Intersectoral Relations, Amsterdam, North Holland.

Rastogi, R. (2002),‘Indian Information Technology Sector – An Overview’, paper presented at a Seminar on Preparation of an Index of Services Production, January 3-4, Organised at Pune by Union Ministry of Finance, Indian Association for Research in National Income & Wealth and National Institute of Bank Management.

Shah, M. (1987), ‘India’s Dream: A Five Per Cent Rate of Growth’, in Brahmananda, P. R. and Panchamukhi, V. R. (edited), The Development Process of the Indian Economy, Bombay: Himalaya Publishing House.

Silver, H. (1987), ‘Only So Many Hours a Day: Time Constraints, Labor Pools, and Demand for Consumer Services’, The Service Industries Journal, 7 (4), 26-45.

Stigler, G. J. (1956), Trends in Employment in the Service Industries, National Bureau of Economic Research, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Triplett, J. and Bosworth, B. (2000), ‘Productivity in the Services Sector’, The Brookings Institution, Washington DC, US.

UNCTAD (1989), Services in the World Economy, Trade and Development Report.

US Department of Commerce (1996), Service Industries and Economic Performance, Economics and Statistics Administration, Office of Policy Development, March.

Wirtz, J. (2001), ‘Growth of the Service Sector in Asia’, Singapore Management Review.

RbiTtsCommonUtility

प्ले हो रहा है
கேட்கவும்

Related Assets

RBI-Install-RBI-Content-Global

RbiSocialMediaUtility

இந்திய ரிசர்வ் வங்கி மொபைல் செயலியை நிறுவுங்கள் மற்றும் சமீபத்திய செய்திகளுக்கான விரைவான அணுகலை பெறுங்கள்!

Scan Your QR code to Install our app

RbiWasItHelpfulUtility

இந்த பக்கம் உதவியாக இருந்ததா?