Financial Sector Reforms: The Indian Experience - ఆర్బిఐ - Reserve Bank of India
Financial Sector Reforms: The Indian Experience
Dr. C. Rangarajan, Governor, Reserve Bank of India
delivered-on మే 18, 1997
Address by C. Rangarajan Governor, Reserve Bank of India at the Bankers' Training Centre of the Nepal Rastra Bank Kathmandu on 18th May 1997
Financial Sector Reforms: The Indian Experience
I. Introduction
- In any economy, the financial sector plays a major role in
the mobilisation and allocation of savings. Financial institutions,
instruments and markets which constitute the financial
sector act as a conduit for the transfer of financial resources
from net savers to net borrowers, i.e. from those who spend less
than they earn to those who earn less than they spend.
- The financial sector performs this basic economic function
of intermediation essentially through four transformation mechanisms :
- liability-asset transformation (i.e.,accepting deposits as a liability and converting them into assets such as loans);
- size-transformation (i.e., providing large loans on the basis of numerous small deposits);
- maturity transformation (i.e., offering savers alternate forms of deposits according to their liquidity preferences while providing borrowers with loans of desired maturities); and
- risk transformation (i.e., distributing risks through diversification
which substantially reduces risks for savers which
would prevail while lending directly in the absence of financial
intermediation).
- The process of financial intermediation supports increasing
capital accumulation through the institutionalisation of savings
and investment and as such, fosters economic growth. The gains
to the real sector of the economy therefore depend on how
efficiently the financial sector performs this basic function of
financial intermediation.
- A distinction is often made in the literature between operational
efficiency and allocational efficiency; while the former
relates to transaction costs, the latter deals with the distribution
of mobilised funds among competing demands. Sustained
improvement of economic activity and growth is greatly enhanced
by the existence of a financial system developed in terms of
both operational and allocational efficiency in mobilising
savings and in channelling them among competing demands. In
addition, functional efficiency of a financial system must be
judged in terms of (a) the soundness of the appraisals as
measured by the level of overdues, (b) the resource cost of
specific operations, and (c) the quality and speed of delivery.
This is an update of author's Fourth SICOM Silver Jubilee Memorial Lecture delivered at Mumbai on 29th July 1996. of services. Both operational and allocational efficiency, to a large extent, are influenced by market structure and the regulatory framework, and on both grounds the central bank has an important role to play in a developing economy like India.
II. Financial Sector Reforms - The Global experience
- The process of changing the character and structure of
financial markets has in many ways been a global phenomenon,
though the motivations for reforming domestic financial markets
have varied from country to country. Issues of financial sector
liberalization and reform, including elements such as effective
bank supervision, changing banking regulations, interest rates
policies, etc., have received attention not only among developing
countries but also a large number of developed countries. The
debt crisis of the early '80s and a series of financial crisis
witnessed, particularly, during the 1980s, accentuated the move
towards adopting measures to impart greater depth, liquidity and
stability to the international financial markets. According to
the BIS more than 30 Governments across the world have had to
help their financial institutions in distress over the last 10
years or so and also bring about consequent changes in their
regulatory environment and market structure.
- The reform of the financial sector in the industrially
advanced countries was triggered to a major extent by the global
isation of banks and the financial markets. The globalisation
trend began at the end of '60s and '70s and was influenced by
factors such as restrictive regulations on banking, like Regulation
Q in the United States. In fact, the creation of the Euro
dollar market was perhaps a precursor to the creation of freer
and market driven financial systems. Further, the collapse of the
Brettonwoods system had ushered in an era of floating exchange
rates in most countries. The subsequent abolition by several
countries of capital controls resulted in the development of
strong cross-border flows and trading. Simultaneous technological
advances in the financial sector strengthened the information
resources of banks enabling them to offer real time buying and
lending of financial assets, creating profit and loss opportunities
throughout the day. These trends were reinforced by the
growth of strong competition among institutions especially from
the non-bank financial institutions. With the distinction between
banks and non-banks coming down, several restrictions
specific to the banking sector got dismantled.
- These developments however raised the level of risk being
handled by the global financial system. While risk rose, the
margins decreased. Response to increasing competition and decreasing
margins came in the form of financial product innovations
engineered particularly so as to remain off-balance sheet.
- Greater opportunities, competitive pressures, financial
deregulation and liberalization however led to a tendency on the
part of the banks and financial institutions to over extend their
lending and investment decisions, such as, by accepting debtors
of lower credit worthiness in an attempt to maintain profitability.
In the mid 80s, these forced the monetary authorities to
strengthen the regulations and raise capital requirements which
came to be popularly known as the `Basle norms'. Rules were laid
down for reporting non-balance sheet items and prescribing higher
risk capital to cover contingencies.
- Apart from the general objective of improving the working of
the financial system, financial sector reforms in many developing
countries in Latin America and Asia, were introduced as part of
an overall programme of economic stabilisation. In some of the
Latin American countries, financial sector reforms were initiated
as early as from the middle of 1970s but in most of the countries
this phenomenon gained prevalence in the mid '80s. While in some
countries financial sector reforms helped in the strengthening of
the financial system, some other countries had to initially face
some setbacks.
- A recent study draws the following lessons from the experience
of several developing countries which introduced financial
liberalisation programmes. First, a minimal system of prudential
regulation is necessary before embarking on financial sector
reforms. Second, the speed and nature of interest rate liberalisation
has to take into account the pace with which problem banks
and their debtors can be restructured. Recapitalising the weak
banks and restructuring their portfolios must receive attention
in this context. Third, the success of the financial liberalisation
programmes critically depends upon maintaining macro economic
control during the reform period. Fourth, introduction of
convertibility should move from trade to current to capital
account.
III. Background of Financial Sector Reform in India
- The financial sector reforms currently underway in India
must be seen as a component, of the overall scheme of structural
reforms. The overall package is aimed at enhancing the productivity
and efficiency of the economy as a whole and also in
creasing international competitiveness. The reforms are comprehensive
in scope covering besides financial sector reforms,
several other components of economic policy including, liberalisation
and deregulation of domestic investment, opening up of key
infrastructure areas hitherto reserved for the public sector for
private sector participation, opening up the economy to foreign
competition by reducing protective barriers such as import
controls and high tariff, encouraging direct foreign investment
as a source of technology upgradation and also as a source of
non-debt finance for investment, reform of the public sector to
impart greater efficiency of operations and reform of the tax
system to create a structure with moderate rates of tax, broader
base of taxation and greater ease of administration. All these
reforms are closely inter-related, and progress in one area helps
to achieve objectives in others. Since the reforms are being
introduced in a phased manner the extent of progress differs
from area to area. Importance of the financial sector reforms in
this structured package needs to be delineated clearly. Structural
reforms in areas such as industrial and trade policy can
succeed only if resources are redeployed towards more efficient
producers which are encouraged to expand under the new policies.
This reallocation is possible only if the financial system plays
a crucial supportive role. The reforms in the banking sector
and in the capital markets are aimed precisely at achieving this
primary objective.
- The Indian financial system comprises an impressive network
of banks and financial institutions and a wide range of financial
instruments. There is no doubt that there has been a considerable
widening and deepening of the Indian financial system, particularly
in the last two decades. The extension of banking and
other financial facilities to a larger cross-section of the
people stands out as a significant achievement.
- Despite the overall progress made by the financial system
in terms of geographic and functional coverage, the balance sheet
of the performance of the banking sector was a mixed one -
strong in widening the credit coverage but weak as far as viability
and sustainability was concerned. It was against this
background that the financial sector reform was initiated aimed
at addressing the causal factors both internal and external to
the system.
IV. Financial Sector Reforms in India: Philosophy and Strategy
- The ongoing financial sector reform programme aims at promoting
a diversified, efficient and competitive financial sector
with the ultimate objective of improving the allocative efficiency
of available resources, increasing the return on invest
ments and promoting an accelerated growth of the real sector of
the economy.
- More specifically, the financial sector reform programme
seeks to achieve the following:
- suitable modifications in the policy framework within which various components of the financial system operate, such as rationalisation of interest rates, reduction in the levels of resource pre-emptions and improving the effectiveness of directed credit programmes;
- improvement in the financial health and competitive capabilities by means of prescription of prudential norms, recapitalisation of banks, restructuring of weaker banks, allowing freer entry of new banks and generally improving the incentive system under which banks function;
- building financial infrastructure relating to supervision, audit, technology and legal framework; and,
- upgradation of the level of managerial competence and the
quality of human resource of banks by reviewing the policies
relating to recruitment, training, and placement.
- There are certain `commandments' or pre-requisites for
systemic reform of the financial sector. First and foremost,
macroeconomic stabilisation is a must during the reform process.
Fiscal and external policies must support monetary policy in
maintaining the overall macroeconomic balance. Secondly, during
the reform period, prudential regulation must be introduced and
adhered to in order to help safeguard against a financial crisis
and prevent the undermining of monetary control and macroeconomic
adjustment. Thirdly, the Government must simultaneously
implement wide-ranging reforms in other sectors, specially those
which require support from the financial system to get the best
results.
V. Salient Features of Financial sector reform in India
- In conformity with the broad philosophy and strategy for
reform, salient features of the financial sector reform in India
could be analysed under three broad categories :
- Policy framework,
- Improvement in financial health, and
- Institutional Strengthening.
(a) Policy Framework
- The external factors bearing on the profitability of the
banking system related to the administered structure of interest
rates, high levels of pre-emptions in the form of reserve requirements,
and credit allocation to certain sectors. Easing of
these external constraints constitutes a
major part of the reform agenda.
(i) Interest Rate Policy
- The reform of the interest regime constitutes an integral
part of the financial sector reform. For long, an administered
structure of interest rates was in vogue. The purpose behind this
structure was largely to direct implicit subsidy to certain
sectors and enable them to obtain funds at concessional rates
of interest. An element of cross subsidisation automatically
got built into the system where concessional rates of interest
provided to some sectors were compensated by higher rates
charged to other non-concessional borrowers. The regulation of
lending rates, ipso facto,led to the regulation of the deposit
rates mainly to keep the cost of funds to banks in reasonable
relation to the rates at which they are required to lend. This
system of setting the interest rates through administrative fiat
became extremely complex and was characterised by detailed
prescriptions on the lending as well as the deposit side.
- In recognition of the problems arising from administrative
control over the interest rates, such as, market fragmentation,
inefficient allocation of resources, and the like, several
attempts were made since the mid-1980s to rationalise the level
and structure of interest rates in the country. Initially,
steps were taken to develop the domestic money market and
freeing of the money market rates. The rates of interest offered
on Government Securities were progressively raised so that the
Government borrowing could be carried out at market-related
rates. The rates at which the corporate entities could borrow
from the capital market were also freed.
- In respect of banks, a major effort was undertaken to
simplify the administered structure of interest rates. In September
1990, a process of simplification was undertaken by reducing
the number of slabs for which lending rates had hitherto
been prescribed. Until some time ago, the Reserve Bank was
prescribing a minimum lending rate, two concessional rates of
lending for small borrowers and a maximum deposit rate. The
rationalisation in the structure of interest rates culminated
in the move by the Reserve Bank, abolishing the minimum lending
rate in October 1994 and leaving banks to determine their prime
lending rates, while retaining the two concessional rates of
lending for small borrowers. On the deposit side, since July 1996
the Reserve Bank prescribes only a maximum rate for deposits upto
one year.
- A gradual approach has thus far been adopted in reforming
the interest rates structure in India. Care has been taken to
ensure that banks and financial intermediaries do not have
incentives which tempt them to lend at high rates of interest
assuming higher risks. A major safeguard in this regard has been
the prescription of prudential norms relating to provisioning
and capital adequacy. These combined with higher standards of
operational accountability and appraisal of credit risks would
ensure that banks lend prudently and with care.
- In the context of the deregulation of interest rates, there
was an urgent need for developing a reference rate to signal the
policy stance of the Reserve Bank. Accordingly, to make the Bank
rate an effective signalling rate, in the monetary and credit
policy for the first half of 1997-98 announced recently there has
been a rationalisation of the interest rate structure with link
ing of several interest rates of significance to the Bank rate.
(ii) Pre-emption of Deposits
- Indian banking system has operated for a long time with a
high level reserve requirements both in the form of Cash Reserve
Ratio and Statutory Liquidity Ratio. This is really a consequence
of the high fiscal deficit and a high degree of monetisa
tion of that deficit. In mid 1991. pre-emption in the form of
CRR and SLR requirements on incremental deposits amounted to 63.5
per cent. Our efforts in the recent period have been to lower
both the CRR and SLR. Apart from removing the incremental CRR,
since 1991, the average CRR has been brought down. The objective
has been to take the CRR to 10 per cent and below. We are already
on this path and the effective CRR has come down from 15.7
per cent at the end of March 1995 to less than 10 per cent by
March 1997. With a view to facilitating the development of a
more realistic rupee yield curve and term money market, liabilities
to banking system have been exempted from maintenance of CRR
since April 1997. The SLR has also been brought down from the
pre-reform peak of an effective rate of 37.5 per cent to an
overall effective level of 26.7 per cent in March 1997. With the
SLR on incremental deposits set at 25 per cent and the exemption
of inter-bank liabilities from SLR, the average SLR will also
come down to 25 per cent.
(iii) Directed Credit
- In respect of directed lending, there is a prescription
that 40 per cent of the net bank credit should go to certain
sectors - the priority sector - such as agriculture, small scale
industry and small businesses and the programmes for
poverty alleviation. Given the imperfections of the credit
market, credit allocation for certain sectors becomes necessary
in the Indian context. The prescription of 40 per cent of net
bank credit going to the priority sector as well as the prescription
of two concessional rates of interest applicable for small
loans have been retained. Since the bulk of borrowers with
such credit needs fall within the priority sector, they will
continue to obtain bank finance at concessional rates. Priority
sector borrowers with credit needs of higher amounts will
however, be governed by the general interest rate prescriptions.
This will ensure that a certain proportion of bank credit goes
to the designated sector and to the needy borrowers, without
unduly affecting the viability and profitability of banks.
(b) Improvement in Financial Health
- Another major element of the financial sector reform has
been the introduction of prudential norms and regulations aimed
at ensuring the safety and soundness of the financial system,
impart greater transparency and accountability in operke these
(financial) markets function better but will also improve the
performance of the economy'. The need for intervention in finan
cial markets is not denied by anyone. All advocates of financial
sector reform have pleaded that deregulation should be accompa
nied if not preceded by putting in place a rigorous set of prudential
standards to be met by financial institutions. As John
Crow former Governor of the Bank of Canada said, 'deregulation
does not mean desupervision'. Internationally accepted common
standards for income recognition, provisioning and capital ade
quacy have come into force in almost all countries. It is when
Stiglitz argues for a more intrusive form of intervention which
includes directed credit and maintaining low interest rates
through a system of financial repression, that differences begin
to emerge. Even here the differences are one of degree rather
than of kind. Stiglitz himself talks of the failure to distinguish
between small and large repressions. While cross subsidisation
of interest rates as well as some forms of directed credit
can be built into a system of credit dispensation, the issue
becomes serious when such subsidisation reaches levels at which
the very viability of the financial institutions is at stake. To
some extent, Stiglitz recognises this when he says that `there is
a role for Government in financial markets but the success of
Government interventions has been mixed. It is important that
intervention be well designed'. In fact, what he calls for, are
imaginative forms of Government intervention. The crux of the
problem lies in determining whether or not a specific policy
intervention is imaginative enough i.e. whether it would be more
effective than reliance on market force. The art of policy
making thus really lies in the eclectic selection of policy
interventions.
- In the context of the banking sector reforms in India, two
issues have been raised which need to be addressed squarely. One
relates to the rate of interest and the other to the prudential
norms. With respect to interest rates the two main questions that
are being raised are -
- should the interest rate be allowed to be determined by market
forces? and
- should Government meet its borrowing requirements by raising
funds at market determined rates of interest?
- should the interest rate be allowed to be determined by market
forces? and
- It is being argued that when market forces are allowed to
determine the rate of interest, the rate will tend to remain high
and such high rates can hinder the process of growth. But these
critics fail to understand that if rates of interest are kept at
artificially low levels, it can only result in diverting funds
from the organised to the unorganised sectors, losing total
control over the end-use of funds. While aggregate savings may
not be significantly influenced by changes in interest rate,
there is enough evidence, nevertheless to show, even in the
Indian context, that savings in the form of financial assets are
considerably influenced by interest rate. Therefore, if the
financial institutions are to perform effectively their major
role of mobilising resources, the rate should be allowed to be
determined by the forces of supply and demand. The interest rate
is, however, a strategic variable and its level can be and is
influenced by the actions of the monetary authority. In that
sense, interest rate nowhere in the world is purely determined by
market forces. It is the function of the monetary authority's
policy intervention through the various instruments available to
it to move the rate of interest towards a level considered appropriate.
Within this overall policy framework, market forces have
a greater role in determining the structure of interest rates
rather than its level. The monetary authority, however, cannot
keep interest rates for long at levels that are inconsistent with
the basic supply and demand balance.
- On the issue of Government borrowing at market related rates
of interest, the only way in which Government can meet its requirements
at below market rates will be either through a mandatory
requirement forcing banks and other financial institutions
to invest a certain proportion of their liabilities in Government
paper or by simply borrowing from the central bank generat
ing an increase in money supply. The first alternative leads to
a situation in which the viability of the financial institutions
themselves gets eroded. While obviously certain liquidity requirements
can be imposed, beyond a point it can only turn the
financial institutions into loss making entities. If Government
borrows excessively from the central bank, it can only fuel
inflation by expanding money supply beyond reasonable limits. It
is some times argued that the high rates of interest that the
Government has to pay on its borrowings worsens the fiscal deficit.
But it is overlooked that high interest rates themselves
are not the cause but the effect of unduly large fiscal deficits.
The answer to reducing the interest payments lies basically in
the Government containing the fiscal deficit and not artificially
trying to keep the rates of interest low. While a high interest
rate may not be a sufficient deterrent in containing borrowing,
nevertheless, it serves a useful function in making explicit the
true cost of Government borrowing.
- Some critics have even taken objection to the introduction
of prudential norms. They regard such an introduction either as
irrelevant or premature. It is indeed surprising that objections
could be raised against introduction of prudential norms. These
norms are basically intended to improve the soundness of the
working of institutions. In order to avoid a serious set back to
the functioning of banks and other institutions, prudential norms
have also been introduced in India in a phased manner. Progressively
the definition of Non Performing Assets has been tightened.
The circumstances prevailing in the Indian financial
sector have been taken into account in determining the phasing in
of prudential norms. The prudential norms have served a useful
role wherever they have been introduced. They have compelled
institutions to pay greater attention to the quality of lending.
It is true that as a consequence of the introduction of capital
adequacy norms, Government have had to allocate a fairly large
amount of funds in order to enable the public sector banks to
achieve the required capital adequacy standards. There has been
no cash outflow because capital has been inducted in the form of
bonds. Nevertheless, there is an outflow as far as the Government
is concerned in the form of interest payments and the phased
amortisation of the bonds. The recapitalisation became neces
sary in order to strengthen the balance sheets of banks. Some
critics have even sought to establish a relationship between
write-off of bad loans and recapitalisation but it is necessary
to recognise that these two are independent processes. Write-off
of bad loans is part of the programme of cleaning the balance-sheet
of banks while recapitalisation has been necessitated by
the weakened financial position. Had the prudential norms been
introduced earlier, much of the problems of non-performing assets
confronted by banks today could have been avoided.
- One argument against liberalisation has been that it could
lead banks to lend at higher and higher rates of interest and
thereby accepting higher levels of risk. Literature describes
this phenomenon as a process of `adverse selection'. In fact, the
answer to adverse selection is the prescription of prudential
norms, which will compel banks not to accept risks beyond a
point. In any case, banks have never been pure profit maximisers.
Profit maximisation has always been subject to the constraint
of acceptable level of risk. The prudential norms make
this constraint explicit.
- The chief merit of our reform process has been the cautious sequencing of reforms and the consistent and mutually reinforcing character of the various measures taken. Introduction of prudential norms, widening of the capital base and strengthening of the organisational infrastructure have all gone hand in hand.
- The first stage of the banking sector reform is coming to an
end and we are now moving on to the next stage of the reform. In
the years to come, the Indian financial system will grow not only
in size but also in complexity as the forces of competition gain
further momentum and as the financial markets acquire greater
width and depth. While the policy environment will remain supportive
of healthy growth and development with accent on greater
operational flexibility as well as greater prudential regulation
and supervision, the thrust of the second phase of reform
would have to be on improvement in the organisational effective
ness of banks and other financial entities.
- Through the various reform measures we have laid the foundation for an efficient and a well-functioning financial system in order to support and sustain a high level of real growth. Significant changes have already taken place. True, as the saying goes, we have miles to go. But our experience so far shows that the steps that have been taken are in the right direction.