RBI WPS (DEPR): 13/2012: Fiscal Stance, Credibility and Inflation Persistence in India - ربی - Reserve Bank of India
RBI WPS (DEPR): 13/2012: Fiscal Stance, Credibility and Inflation Persistence in India
RBI Working Paper Series No. 13 Abstract †In the recent past India has experienced high and persistent inflation. In response the Reserve Bank of India cumulatively raised the cash reserve ratio by 100 basis points and the policy rate (repo rate) by 375 basis points between January 2010 and October 2011. Despite these policy actions, the inflation rate however continues to remain stubbornly high. What explains our current inflation predicament? This paper finds that large contemporary government deficits unaccompanied by concrete prospects for future government surpluses promote realistic doubts about whether monetary restraint must be abandoned sooner or later to help finance the deficit. The result will be a rise in inflationary expectations in spite of current money-supply restraint- a bout of unpleasant monetarist arithmetic. In sum, it is insufficient to announce and maintain restrictive monetary policies unless accompanied by a coordinated reduction in the budget deficits. Prudent anti-inflation policy includes containment of the deficit. JEL classifications: E31; E44; E52 Keywords: Inflation Persistence; Credibility; Fiscal policy; Kalman Filter 1. IntroductionSince the global financial turmoil of 2008 the Indian economy has grappled with high and persistent inflation. The headline inflation measured by wholesale price index (WPI) hovered in the range of 9-10 per cent in every month between February 2010 and November 2011, way above the RBI's comfort zone.1 There is growing apprehension that the recent inflationary experience might well be the ‘new normal’ for an economy like ours. The concern is not just the level of inflation, but also its persistence. To deal with the inflationary pressure, the Reserve Bank cumulatively raised the cash reserve ratio (CRR) by 100 basis points and the policy rate (the repo rate) by 375 basis points between January 2010 and October 2011. Despite these policy actions, the inflation rate however continues to remain persistently high. What explains our current inflation predicament? It is often claimed that stubbornly high inflation is because of “temporary factors or cost shocks” such as an increase in oil or commodity prices. According to this widely held view inflation is largely a non-monetary phenomenon: it is driven by “cost-push” factors, and these factors dominate the behaviour of inflation regardless of what course monetary or fiscal policy takes.2 It has also become fashionable in certain circles to assert that the way to deal with the problem is by microeconomic policy- the panoply of controls and subsidies associated with a different era.3 Economic theory teaches us that inflation persistence is a product of the forcing processes (shocks) interacting with the policy regime. It is perfectly reasonable to find that these shocks are themselves auto-correlated. These processes will propagate themselves through all the endogenous variables and be a natural source of persistence. Monetary authorities (in the absence of fiscal constraints) could choose to close this persistence down if they wish by credibly committing to price stability. So what explains rise and fall in inflation persistence? There is a growing body of research which links persistence to policy regime credibility (see Brainard and Perry (2000), Taylor (2000) and Kim et al. (2001), Ravenna (2000), Benati (2004) and Levin et al. (2004)). For example, inflation was approximately a white noise process in both the U.S. and the U.K. during the gold standard regime and exhibited considerable persistence in the post war era. In fact, major inflation episodes around the world have ultimately resulted from fiscal problems and it is hard to think of a fiscally sound country that has ever experienced high and persistent inflation. So long as the government’s fiscal house is in order, people will naturally assume that the central bank should be able to stop a small uptick in inflation. Conversely, when the government's finances are in disarray, inflation expectations can become “unanchored” very quickly. But this link between fiscal and monetary expectations is too often ignored by both policymakers and the popular press.4 The basic point is that fiscal deficits today must be paid for by taxes, money expansions or lower expenditure tomorrow (the government’s inter-temporal budget constraint). If one assumes any reasonable termination of the rising debt/GDP ratio, whether because of a limit on incentive damaging taxes, then money financing is eventually required in the absence of quite implausibly severe cuts in public expenditure. This means a rise in future inflation is worse than the moderation in current inflation from current money-supply restraint. This analysis was spread widely by Sargent and Wallace (1981) in their well known paper ‘Some unpleasant monetarist arithmetic’. From the government’s inter-temporal budget constraint, if the fiscal house is not in order in the present and the future, then this implies monetary restraint will be abandoned sooner or later to ensure solvency. This would undermine credibility of the monetary regime as inflationary expectations would remain elevated. Hence the ‘unpleasant’ policy lesson that the budget deficit must also be cut back to make a monetarist inflation-control programme work. By implication contractionary monetary policy signalling the authorities’ wish to halt inflation may not be credible unless accompanied by a coordinated reduction in the budget deficits. Therefore, in order to establish counter-inflationary credibility it is not sufficient just for the monetary authority to be responsible. We need fiscal stance to be responsible too. In the literature, there exist different approaches to explain lag dynamics in inflation. One such approach relies on imperfect credibility and learning (see Erceg and Levin (2003) and Westelius (2005)). The idea is that, if the announced inflation target lacks credibility (say because of fiscal constraints), then inflation expectations will not be significantly affected. Facing imperfect credibility the policy maker perceives a quick disinflation to be extremely costly and consequently finds it optimal to gradually reduce inflation – higher persistence. Thus, these models predict that a monetary regime that lacks credibility, learning by private agents can generate a significant amount of inflation persistence. In contrast, a policy regime that enjoys credibility, agents learn quickly, resulting in a drop in inflation persistence.5 From an empirical standpoint the credibility literature predicts that the degree of inflation persistence should negatively covary with policy regime credibility. This paper attempts to empirically evaluate this hypothesis using Indian data. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a brief description of the inflationary trend since the 1950s. Section 3 traces the historical evolution of monetary-fiscal interface. Section 4 presents the theoretical model of imperfect credibility, learning and inflation persistence. In Section 5, we empirically evaluate the link between policy regime credibility and inflation persistence. Our empirical methodology, data used in the analysis and our empirical results are also discussed. Section 6 concludes. 2. Inflationary trend in India: A long-term view Price stability has been an important objective of monetary policy in India. In fact, India’s inflation performance compares favourably against other emerging market economies. The 1950s witnessed average inflation of less than 2 per cent, but with considerable variation in yearly inflation. During the 1960s, the average decadal inflation edged up to 6.3 per cent, on account of wars and unsatisfactory agricultural supply position. Like most other developed and developing countries the decade of 1970s was the most turbulent period when it comes to India’s inflation history. The average inflation was 9 per cent in that decade. Figure 1 shows all commodities WPI inflation since the early 1980s (summary statistics in Table 1). We have split our sample 1983:4 to 2011:1 into different segments with each segment corresponding to a statistically distinct mean of overall inflation compared with the adjoining segment. This periodisation of the data is based on the Bai and Perron (2003) test of multiple structural breaks at unknown dates where the optimal breakpoints are estimated from the data itself. For the period beginning April 1983 up to January 2012, average headline inflation measured in terms of year-on-year increase in all commodities wholesale price index (WPI) has been 6.9 per cent. While the primary (7.9 per cent) and fuel groups (9.0 per cent) have been the high and volatile components, the manufactured group (6.1 per cent) component has been low and stable. There was a palpable decline in both the level and volatility of headline inflation during the first half of the 1980s from those seen in the 1970s. Inflation picked up during the latter part of the 1980s fuelled mainly by the manufactured group. An important factor behind rising inflationary pressures of the 1980s was expansionary fiscal policy. Figure 1: Multiple structural breaks in inflation
The fiscal deficit of the central government increased from 3.8 per cent of GDP during the 1970s to 6.8 per cent during the 1980s. Approximately, one-third of this burden was borne by Reserve Bank of India (RBI) through automatic monetization of budget deficit which in turn led to a rapid acceleration in reserve money growth. The experience of this decade highlighted the importance of fiscal-monetary coordination in fighting inflation and paved the way for enhanced monetary autonomy.7 Increasingly, expansionist fiscal stance spilled over to the external sector. The Indian economy underwent a severe economic crisis in 1991 mainly triggered by a balance of payment problem and manifestation of underlying imbalances emanating from an adverse impact of high budget and current account deficits of the 1980s. Following the Gulf crisis of 1991, the first half of the decade was characterized by double-digit inflation, with high inflation in the primary and fuel group segment joining hands with the already high inflation in the manufactured group. The high inflation of this period was a result of several factors: devaluation of exchange rate, very low foreign exchange reserves precluding imports to meet the demand gap, hike in procurement prices and supply-demand imbalances in some essential commodities, sustained rise in fuel prices, and monetary expansion resulting from the surge in capital inflows with the advent of opening up of the economy. For more than a decade starting from the mid-1990s until early 2008, India witnessed the longest period of benign inflation averaging around 5 per cent on account of subdued inflation in both primary as well as manufactured group, although inflation in the fuel group remained elevated. This was a commendable performance in view of substantial capital inflows and several other adverse developments such as Asian financial crisis, border tensions with Pakistan and high commodity prices. This turnaround in the inflationary trend is partly explained by the improved monetary-fiscal interface and reforms in the government securities market enabling a lower degree of monetisation of fiscal deficits. A particularly noteworthy step was the historic accord between the government and the RBI for phasing out the issue of automatic monetization of budget deficit. This in turn reinforced monetary policy autonomy and enhanced central bank credibility. Moreover, by the end of the decade of 1990s the reform measures undertaken to liberalize the economy started to bear fruit, as there was a surge in productivity growth. With productivity growth on an uptrend and the trend growth rate of the economy moving on to a higher trajectory, inflationary pressure subsided. In addition, factors such as containment of global inflation, lower order of depreciation of exchange rate and weaker pass-through, comfortable level of buffer stocks of food grains and foreign exchange reserves may also have played their part in keeping inflation under check. The period from March 2008 to January 2012 represents another phase of high inflation averaging around 7.6 per cent. In various reports and policy documents, the Reserve Bank attributed the stubborn inflation of this phase to: (i) food inflation resulting from long-term change in the dietary pattern, (ii) food inflation permeating into the core/generalised inflation via changes in inflationary expectations and wage-price spiral, (iii) buoyant demand conditions enabling producers to pass on the increase in input cost to the final price, (iv) elevated international commodity prices on account of ultra accommodative monetary policy in major advanced economies, depreciating exchange rate and geo-political uncertainties, and (v) fiscal stimulus largely of the nature of consumption expenditure in response to the 2008 financial crisis stoking inflation and inflationary expectations. Apart from its level, an important empirical property of an observed inflation measure is its persistence.8 The purpose of focusing attention on persistence is to isolate changes in the dynamic response of inflation to shocks around its mean from changes in the mean of inflation itself. Figure 2 plots a 3-year rolling window estimate of first order autocorrelation of the inflation series. The evidence in figure points towards time variation in inflation persistence even after accounting for time variation in the mean of the series. We observe that while persistence increased from the late 1980s to early 1990s, it stabilized thereafter. We once again witness an upward drift following the global financial crisis. What explains this turnaround? We explore these issues later in the paper. Figure 2: 3-year rolling window estimate of first-order autocorrelation in inflation 3. Evolution of Monetary-Fiscal Interface in India The legal basis of the monetary-fiscal interface in India is enshrined in the RBI Act, 1934, under which the Reserve Bank manages the public debt of the Central and the State Governments and also acts as a banker to them. The monetary-fiscal coordination, however, has been a continuously evolving process reflecting the institutional framework of the time. In the colonial settings of the pre-independence era, the British Government adopted a stance of fiscal neutrality and the Reserve Bank’s role was restricted only to the day-to-day management of the financial system. Notwithstanding this, the financing requirements of the World War II necessitated the Government to take recourse to primary accommodation from the Reserve Bank. Post-independence, India embarked on the path of planned economic development. Fiscal policy was geared to exert a ‘big push’ to the low level of saving and investment in the economy by setting up public sector companies. According to the Report of the Working Group on Operating Procedure of Monetary Policy, “During this period, the conduct of monetary policy was influenced significantly by the need to support plan financing and promote savings for its deployment to sectors in accordance with plan priorities. The large plan financing led to the RBI accommodating deficit financing of the government through the issue of ad hoc Treasury Bills from the beginning of Second Five-Year Plan. This led to the conduct of monetary policy becoming a process of passive accommodation of budget deficits by the early 1960s.” In addition to the ad hoc Treasury Bills, monetisation of deficits was also a result of the Reserve Bank’s subscription to primary issuances of Government securities as financial markets were under-developed and were unable to absorb the large government borrowings required for plan financing. As the debt-manager of the Government, the Reserve Bank was forced to control the cost of Government borrowings. To neutralise the impact of monetary accommodation, the Reserve Bank of India (Amendment) Act, 1956 empowered the Reserve Bank to vary cash reserve ratio, which was hitherto fixed. An important amendment of the Banking Regulation Act, 1949 came in 1962 which excluded the balances maintained under Cash Reserve Ratio (CRR) from being reckoned under Statutory Liquidity Ratio (SLR) in order to prevent banks from liquidating their Government securities to meet higher reserve requirements. The gradual increase in minimum SLR requirements along with nationalisation of banks in 1969 provided an increasing captive investor base for Government securities as the fiscal situation deteriorated. The Government’s efforts to arrest the increasing inflationary pressures of the 1960s and 1970s included mainly selective credit control and a system of administered prices. The public finances of the Central Government started deteriorating in the 1970s and 1980s. With accommodative monetary policy, the rising deficit led to phenomenal growth in reserve money. To neutralise the same and stem inflationary pressures, the Reserve Bank took recourse to progressive increases in CRR, SLR and the Bank Rate during the 1970s and 1980s. With worsening fiscal situation and its attendant monetary impact in the 1980s, there was an increasing recognition for pursuing development strategy consistent with price stability. Against this backdrop, the Committee to Review the Working of the Monetary System (Chairman: Prof. S. Chakravarty, 1985) made comprehensive recommendations for the adoption of a flexible monetary targeting framework with feedback from the real sector, whereby growth of broad money as a nominal anchor was targeted in line with economic growth and an acceptable level of inflation. The tipping point of persistent fiscal imbalances was reached in 1991 with the unprecedented external payment crisis. Monetization of budget deficits in the 1980s fuelled double digit inflation. The crisis underscored the importance of fiscal correction. Recognising this, a sharp correction in fiscal deficit was implemented in 1991-92 and fiscal consolidation was continued through expenditure compression measures and by reducing the reliance on monetization during 1990-91 to 1996-97. A landmark event in the monetary-fiscal interface was reached with the agreement between the Government and the Reserve Bank in 1994 through which the ad hoc treasury bills were completely phased out as on end-March 1997. The easing of fiscal dominance paved the way for reduction in CRR and SLR and restoring the latter’s role as a prudential instrument. Alongside, the government market borrowing through auctions since 1992-93 led to development of a secondary market in government securities and the market determination of interest rates. However, the need for growing market borrowings at reasonable cost required the Reserve Bank to adopt a strategy of appropriately combining devolvement/private placements with open market operations. The monetary-fiscal coordination has entered a new phase with the enactment of the FRBM Act, 2003 under which the Reserve Bank has been prohibited from subscribing to government securities in the primary market from April 1, 2006. 4. A model of credibility, learning and inflation persistence The starting point for the imperfect credibility literature is that following a prolonged period of inflation, an announcement by the central bank that in future the inflation target will be consistent with price stability does not command immediate credibility (Erceg and Levin, 2003). Agents must judge the central bank’s credibility of intent, that is, whether the target represents the true goal of the central bank and its credibility of action, that is, whether the central bank has the ability to meet the target even if it wants to (say, in the face of fiscal constraints). Learning takes time. And the longer the period during which inflation was high, the longer it is likely to be before the private sector is persuaded that policy has changed. In the 1980s fiscal controls weakened and deficits mounted. Increasingly expansionist fiscal stance spilled over to the external sector, requiring growing recourse to external borrowing on commercial terms. Against a background of rising trade and current account deficits and a deteriorating external debt profile, the 1990 Gulf War and consequent oil price spike tipped India's balance of payments into crisis in 1990-91. This period is associated with substantial rise in inflation persistence. In 1991 the central government seized the opportunity offered by the crisis to launch an array of long overdue and wide-ranging economic reforms. They encompassed fiscal consolidation and reform of the tax system, which kept a check on government borrowings. The persistence coefficient stabilized during this phase. This was followed by a period of steady deterioration in government finances during the late 1990s. Our persistence estimate starts to drift up during this phase.14 Figure 3: Persistence estimates and gross primary deficit Finally, in the aftermath of the global financial crisis of 2008, we see a significant deterioration in government finances (mainly due to large public sector pay increases following the Sixth Pay Commission and Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MGNREGA)). In response to the financial crisis, monetary and fiscal policies were eased by allowing for a pause in the fiscal consolidation process enjoined by the FRBM Act of 2003. Moreover, there are increasing indications that meeting the targets adopted in the revised road map for fiscal consolidation as recommended by the Thirteenth Finance Commission would pose a formidable challenge. In sum, government finances are once again in disarray and are not expected to improve over the foreseeable future. This has clearly undermined public confidence in RBI's ability to stabilise inflation going forward. We see a rise in inflation persistence during this phase. The policy implications of this paper are quite clear. Prudent anti-inflation policy includes containment of the deficit to an amount that can be comfortably financed at steady interest rates without printing money. Large contemporary government deficits unaccompanied by concrete prospects for future government surpluses promote realistic doubts about whether monetary restraint must be abandoned sooner or later to help finance the deficit. It is insufficient to announce and maintain restrictive monetary policies. Agents will also look at fiscal policy in their attempt to determine whether the ‘reform’ can be sustained. If fiscal policy is incompatible with the ‘reform’ in monetary policy, agents will attach positive probability to the event that the reform will be abandoned in the future. The result will be an increase in inflationary expectations. If so, agents will try to get rid of money today- driving up the prices of goods, services, and eventually wages across the entire economy. Our economy will be primed for it as long as our fiscal trajectory is unsustainable. In sum, it is insufficient to announce and maintain restrictive monetary policies unless accompanied by a coordinated reduction in the budget deficits. * Disclaimer: Any opinions, findings and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the institutions they represent. @ The authors are Research Officer in the Department of Economic and Policy Research and Assistant Adviser in the Department of Statistics and Information Management of the Reserve Bank, respectively. They are currently pursuing their Ph.D. at the Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research (IGIDR), Mumbai. They can be contacted at their respective e-mail ids pankajk@rbi.org.in and pmitra@rbi.org.in. † They would like to thank Dr. Naveen Srinivasan, Associate Professor, IGIDR for intellectual inputs and guidance on both theoretical and technical aspects of the paper. They would also like to thank the anonymous referee for invaluable comments and suggestions. 1 Although RBI does not have target band for inflation, the conduct of monetary policy continues to condition and contain perception of inflation in the range of 4.0-4.5 per cent. This is in line with the medium-term objective of 3.0 per cent inflation consistent with India’s broader integration into the global economy. 2 For example Balakrishnan (1991) concluded that inflation in India was driven mainly by supply shocks. Structuralists argue that inflation occurs because of structural bottlenecks in the agricultural sector. Sectoral imbalances (caused by rapid growth of the industrial sector) lead to an excess demand for agricultural goods and, consequently, a rise in agricultural commodity prices. The increase in raw material prices and the indexation of money wages to the consumer price index results in the transmission of the rise in agricultural prices to industrial prices as firms simply pass on the increase in costs to the consumers. 3 Milton Friedman, writing in 1978, observed that in diagnosing the inflation problem, there were many factors other than money that politicians, economists and journalists write about...[They] attribut[e] the acceleration of inflation to special events - bad weather, food shortages, labor-union intransigence, corporate greed, the OPEC cartel...(cited in Nelson, 2005). Recalling this period a quarter-century later, Friedman argued: Central banks performed badly prior to the 80s... because they [had] a wrong theory.... Inflation, according to this vision, was produced primarily by pressures on cost that could best be restrained by direct controls on prices and wages. 4 There are exceptions of course. In fact, in its Third Quarter Review of Monetary Policy 2011-12, the Reserve Bank of India notes that “the anticipated fiscal slippage, which is caused largely by high levels of consumption spending by the government, poses a significant threat to both inflation management and, more broadly, to macroeconomic stability.” It further states that “strong signs of fiscal consolidation, which will shift the balance of aggregate demand from public to private and from consumption to capital formation, are critical to create the space for lowering the policy rate without the imminent risk of resurgent inflation.” In an interview to the Wall Street Journal on February 13, 2012, Governor Subbarao said “If you see our monetary policy statement over the past two years, we’ve consistently drawn attention to the fiscal deficit concerns having recognised that some stimulus was of course necessary as part of crisis management. However, we thought that this was an appropriate time this time around to call a more pointed attention to this, because this year, the current fiscal year, the fiscal deficit has breached the initial budget estimate and there are a lot of expenditure demands piling up as we see from the newspapers. So we thought it important to call attention to the inflationary dimensions of the fiscal deficit, inasmuch as we have combating inflation over the past two years. To summarize, we did call attention to our concerns to fiscal deficit but did so more pointedly this time around because it was a more appropriate and more opportune time to do that.” 5 Erceg and Levin (2003) formulate a DSGE model in which households and firms use optimal filtering to disentangle persistent and transitory shifts in the central bank’s inflation target. Their calibrated model for the U.S. exhibits moderate persistence of inflation when monetary regime is transparent and credible and much higher persistence when agents use signal extraction to make inferences about the central bank’s inflation target. 6 Primary group (weight: 20.1 per cent) consists of food and non-food articles and minerals. Fuel group (weight: 14.9 per cent) contains coal, mineral oils and electricity. Manufactured group (weight: 65.0 per cent) consists of food products, beverages, tobacco and tobacco products, textiles, wood and wood products, paper and paper products, leather and leather products, rubber and plastic products, chemicals and chemical products, non-metallic mineral products, basic metal, alloys and metal products, machinery and machine tools, and transport, equipments and parts. 7 Some studies have empirically confirmed the existence of vicious circle operating from higher monetisation of fiscal deficit leading to higher inflation which in turn gave rise to higher fiscal deficit (Rangarajan and Arif, 1990). 9 Westelius (2005) on the other hand defines credibility of the policy regime through the relationship between the relative weight assigned by the central bank to inflation variability in the loss function and inflation expectations. Since the public cannot observe the true value of this parameter, they are forced to infer this based on actual inflation realisation. This model also gives rise to persistence in inflation and unemployment. 11 To test the Sargent and Wallace (1981) theory of ‘Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic’, the appropriate data is primary deficit, which is the indicator of current fiscal stance. The standard proxy for credibility in the literature is data on bond yield. We do not use this as a proxy because during most of the 1980s the debt market in India was dominated by government securities primarily due to large fiscal deficits and banking regulations that forced banks to invest in government securities. The interest rate on government debt was administered and there was hardly any secondary market for these securities. Although a significant degree of deregulation has taken place in the recent past, there is still captive demand for government debt. Nearly 70% of the debt is owned either by the RBI or by the banking system which remains dominated by state-owned lenders. As a result it would be inappropriate to use bond yields as a proxy for credibility. 12 For a detailed discussion on Kalman Filter and the TVP model see Anderson and Moore (1979), Harvey (1989) and Durbin and Koopman (2001). 13 When we estimated the model for a longer sample the coefficient was positive but not significant. This is consistent with the view that until the beginning of the 1980s the overall fiscal situation was under control with very low deficits (see Chelliah, 1996). In fact, it is only during the eighties that the fiscal situation steadily deteriorated. This resulted in increasing additions to unproductive debt and the interest burden on the general budget began to grow exponentially.14 Primary deficits witnessed significant decline during 2002-03 to 2005-06 but averaged around 2 per cent of GDP prior to the two exceptional years of primary surpluses – 2006-07 and 2007-08. Correspondingly, the rise in persistence is much lower during this period as compared to the 1980s when primary deficits averaged around 5 per cent of GDP. References [1] Anderson, B.D.O. and J.B. Moore, (1979), “Optimal Filtering”, Prentice-Hall. [2] Balakrishnan, Pulapre, (1991), “Pricing and Inflation in India”, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. [3] Baxter, Marianne, (1985), “The Role of Expectations in Stabilization Policy”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 15, pp. 343-62. [4] Benati, L., (2004), “Evolving post-world war II UK economic performance”, Journal of Money Credit and Banking 36, 691–717. [5] Blackburn, K. and M. Christensen, (1989), “Monetary Policy and Policy Credibility: Theories and Evidence”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 27, No. 1, pp. 1-45. [6] Brainard, W., Perry, G., (2000), “Making policy in a changing world”, In: Perry, G., Tobin, J. (Eds.), Economic Events, Ideas and Policies: The 1960s and After. Brookings Institution Press. [7] Bomfim, Antulio N., and Glenn D. Rudebusch, (2000), “Opportunistic and Deliberate Disinflation Under Imperfect Credibility”. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32, 707-21. [8] Chelliah, Raja J., (1996), “Towards Sustainable Growth: Essays in Fiscal and Financial Sector Reforms in India”, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. [9] Cogley, T., Primiceri, G.E., Sargent, T.J., (2010), “Inflation-gap persistence in the U.S.”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (1), 43–69. [10] Durbin, J. and Koopman S.J., (2001), “Time Series Analysis by State Space Method”, Oxford University Press. [11] Erceg, Christopher J., and Andrew T. Levin, (2003), “Imperfect Credibility and Inflation Persistence”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 915-44. [12] Harvey, A. C. (1989), “Forecasting, structural time series models and the Kalman filter”, Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. [13] King, Mervyn, (1996), “How Should Central Banks Reduce Inflation?- Conceptual Issues”, in Achieving Price Stability, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Kansas City, MO: pp. 53-91. [14] Kim, C., Nelson, C., Piger, J., (2001), “The less volatile US economy: a Bayesian investigation of timing, breadth, and potential explanations”, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers No. 707. [15] Levin, A., Natalucci, F., Piger, J., (2004), “The macroeconomic effects of inflation targeting”, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 86, 4, pp. 51–80. [16] Rangarajan, C. and R.R. Arif, (1990), “Money, Output and Prices: A Macro Econometric Model”, Economic and Political Weekly, April 21, 1990, pp.837-52. [17] Reserve Bank of India, (2006), “The Evolution of Central Banking in India”, Report on Currency and Finance 2004-05. [18] ____________________(2011), Report of the Working Group on Operating Procedure of Monetary Policy. [19] ____________________(2011), “Sustainability of Economic Growth and Controlling Inflation: The Way Forward”, Address by Dr. Subir Gokarn, Deputy Governor at FICCI's National Executive Committee Meeting at Mumbai, April 5, 2011. [20] _____________________(2012), Third Quarter Review of Monetary Policy for 2011-12, January 24, 2012. [21] _____________________(2012), Interview of RBI Governor, Dr. D Subbarao by Mr. Alex Frangos of The Wall Street Journal, February 13, 2012. [22] Ravenna, F., (2000), “The impact of inflation targeting in Canada: a structural analysis”, New York University, mimeo. [23] Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace, (1981), “Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic”, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review. [24] Sargent, Thomas J., (1982), “The End of Four Big Inflations”, in Inflation, Causes and Effects, ed. by Robert E. Hall, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [25] Taylor, J., (2000), “Low inflation, pass-through and the pricing power of firms”, European Economic Review 44, 1389–1408. [26] Westelius, Niklas J., (2005), “Discretionary monetary policy and inflation persistence”, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 52(2), pages 477-496. |