RbiSearchHeader

Press escape key to go back

Past Searches

Theme
Theme
Text Size
Text Size
S1

RbiAnnouncementWeb

RBI Announcements
RBI Announcements

Asset Publisher

79399419

IV. Government Finances (Part 1 of 2)

Central Government Finance,2002-03
State Government Finances,2002-032
Combined Budgetary Position of the Center and States

4.1 The slowing of economic activity due to the drought impacted on public finances in 2002-03. In the revised estimates, the combined gross fiscal deficit of the Centre and States overshot its budgeted level by more than one per cent of GDP on account of the shortfall in tax revenue and disinvestment from budget estimates. Furthermore, the imperatives for food supply management in the context of the drought necessitated fiscal support in the form of higher food subsidies, which surged back almost to 1991-92 level as a proportion to GDP. Despite these setbacks, there were distinct gains in expenditure management. The Centre reined in its expenditure by pruning non-plan spending. On the other hand, the States' expenditure exceeded budget estimates, but this was mainly in the form of a spurt in capital expenditure towards debt consolidation. Importantly, States were able to contain the revenue expenditure around the budgeted level. Notwithstanding these modest successes in expenditure containment, the slippages from the budgetary projections underscore the deterioration in the quality of fiscal adjustment.

4.2 The tax-GDP ratio has been losing buoyancy over the 1990s, falling by more than two per cent of GDP by the year 2001-02 from the level attained in the late 1980s. This imparts urgency to reforms in the tax regime in the form of simplification of rules, widening the tax base, reviewing exemptions and improving compliance. The surge in interest payments following reforms in budgetary financing has continued unabated, and it is only in 2002-03 that some moderation in pace has set in. The steady improvement in the primary deficit coupled with fall in capital outlay during the 1990s indicates that the burden of the unrelenting expansion in interest outgoes has devolved on productive elements of fiscal spending. The overarching priority attached to reduction of expenditure to meet deficit targets has accentuated the erosion of capital outlays with serious implications for expanding the productive capacity of the economy in the future. Expenditure on subsidies has remained impervious to fiscal adjustment, while spending on social infrastructure continues to remain low. Large gaps in disinvestment have intensified the fiscal stress. Reflecting these adverse developments, the debt-GDP ratio has been climbing since the second half of the 1990s and is expected to touch 77 per cent of GDP by the end of March 2004. Moreover, the monotonic rise in public debt has eroded the Government sector’s ability to generate savings and to service its internal debt. The 'quality' of the fiscal deficit has worsened, with the revenue deficit having increased substantially indicating that a larger share of borrowed fund is pre-empted by consumption expenditure. (Table 4.1).

Table 4.1: Indicators of Fiscal Policy


Items

2003-04

2002-03

2001-02

1995-96

1990-91

(BE)

(RE)


1

2

3

4

5

6


(Per cent of GDP)


Quantitative Indicators

Gross Fiscal Deficit

9.2

10.1

9.9

6.5

9.4

Revenue Deficit

5.9

6.7

6.9

3.2

4.2

Primary Deficit

2.8

3.6

3.7

1.6

5.0

Qualitative Indicators

Revenue Receipts

19.0

19.1

17.4

18.3

18.6

Tax Revenue

15.1

14.9

13.7

14.7

15.4

Direct Taxes

4.3

4.2

3.6

3.5

2.5

Indirect Taxes

10.8

10.7

10.1

11.2

12.9

Total Expenditure

29.6

30.4

28.5

25.6

28.8

Developmental

Expenditure

14.6

15.4

14.3

13.9

17.4

Non-developmental

15.0

15.1

14.1

11.6

11.4

Expenditure

Interest Payments

6.4

6.5

6.2

5.0

4.4

Debt

76.9

75.5

71.1

58.0

61.7


(Per cent)


Capital Outlay/

Total Expenditure

11.2

9.6

9.0

10.7

13.1

Interest Payments/

Revenue Receipts

33.7

34.0

35.6

27.2

23.6

Revenue Deficit/

GFD

64.0

66.7

70.4

48.8

44.6


Note : All indicators are based on combined data of the Centre and States. For States, data are provisional for the years 2001-02 onwards.

CENTRAL GOVERNMENT FINANCES, 2002-03

Expenditure Management

4.3 Expenditure management strategies put in place by the Centre since the second half of the 1990s have begun to yield room for fiscal manoeuvre, notwithstanding the slippages in terms of deficit indicators in the recent years. Despite additional expenditure on account of drought relief and Plan allocations, cuts in non-Plan expenditure enabled a reduction in overall spending (as per revised estimates vis-à-vis budget estimates) by the Centre in 2002-03. The reduction in non-Plan expenditure was on account of lower defence spending, reduced interest payments due to softening in the interest rate on Government securities, lower outgo on pension as well as grants and loans to States and UTs due to non-utilisation of funds under the 'Fiscal Incentive Fund'. The expenditure on subsidies, however, increased significantly during 2002-03 reflecting the impact of dismantling of the Administered Price Mechanism (APM) for petroleum products as also the increase in food subsidy on account of drought conditions. Till the dismantling of the APM, subsidies on various petroleum products were absorbed in the oil pool account. With the discontinuance of the latter since 2002-03, the subsidies for domestic Liquefied Petroleum Gas (LPG), Public Distribution System (PDS) kerosene and freight for far flung areas now fall on the budget (Table 4.2).

Table 4.2 : Aggregate Expenditure of the Centre

(Rupees crore)


2002-03

2002-03

2001-02

1995-96

1990-91

Variation between RE

(RE)

(BE)

and BE (2002-03)


Amount

Per cent


1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8


Total Expenditure

4,04,013

4,10,309

3,62,453

1,78,275

1,05,298

-6,296

-1.5

(1+2=3+4)

(16.3)

(16.0)

(15.8)

(15.0)

(18.5)

1.

Non-Plan Expenditure

2,89,924

2,96,809

2,61,259

1,31,901

76,933

-6,885

-2.3

of which:

(11.7)

(11.6)

(11.4)

(11.1)

(13.5)

Interest Payments

1,15,663

1,17,390

1,07,460

50,045

21,498

-1,727

-1.5

(4.7)

(4.6)

(4.7)

(4.2)

(3.8)

Defence

56,000

65,000

54,266

26,856

15,426

-9,000

-13.8

(2.3)

(2.5)

(2.4)

(2.3)

(2.7)

Subsidies

44,618

39,801

31,207

12,666

12,158

4,817

12.1

(1.8)

(1.6)

(1.4)

(1.1)

(2.1)

2.

Plan Expenditure

1,14,089

1,13,500

1,01,194

46,374

28,365

589

0.5

(4.6)

(4.4)

(4.4)

(3.9)

(5.0)

3.

Revenue Expenditure

3,41,648

3,40,482

3,01,611

1,39,861

73,516

1,166

0.3

(13.8)

(13.3)

(13.1)

(11.8)

(12.9)

4.

Capital Expenditure@

62,365

69,827

60,842

38,414

31,782

-7,462

-10.7

(2.5)

(2.7)

(2.6)

(3.2)

(5.6)


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

@ Includes capital outlays and loans and advances.

Note : Figures in brackets are per cent of GDP.

4.4 The gains in expenditure restraint, albeit limited, have strengthened the commitment to fiscal consolidation. They have prepared the ground for adequate forecasting and financial planning so as to ensure that the overall gains of fiscal prudence are also reflected in efficient intra-year cash management. Effective cash management helps in conserving scarce cash resources and ultimately, in controlling aggregate spending and the budgetary gap. In the context of Central Government finances, it is observed that the intra-year divergence between revenue flows and expenditure is high. There is also a tendency of bunching of expenditure during the latter part of the fiscal year (Chart IV.1).

4.5 The initiative to introduce cash management on a pilot basis in major spending Ministries in the 2003-04 budget needs to be seen as an important step forward towards effective expenditure management. The cross-country experience indicates that the time-sliced release of funds for spending and incentive-based cash management practices contribute to overall fiscal discipline (Box IV.1).

Box IV.1
Public Expenditure : Cash Management

Public expenditure management involves determination of the size of the budget, size of the outlays on different functions and the magnitude of outlays on various programmes within the resource constraints at various stages of government decision making. A core element of public expenditure management is cash management which involves conservation and optimisation of cash flow and a sensitivity to cash costs. Effective cash management involves (a) forecast of receipts, disbursements and the resulting cash balances within the governmental financial system on a high frequency basis; (b) strict control over cash inflows to minimise time lags between expected and actual receipts; (c) cash outflow control to prevent both late and premature payments; and (d) minimising operating cash balances.

Cross-country experience indicates that three types of practices for releasing funds are in existence. In countries where budgeted amounts are available soon after the budget is approved (few British Commonwealth countries and some economies in transition), a system of time-sliced releases is in existence. An alternative arrangement is one under which formal warrants are issued by the Ministry of Finance in response to requests from the spending agencies. Such requests have no defined periodicity and primarily reflect the changing seasonal requirements for outlays other than those on personnel. Under the third type of arrangement, fixed amounts are released for commitment and payment on either a monthly or a quarterly cycle.

All these arrangements regulate the release of cash rather than amounts of cash to be credited to spending agencies. Institutional arrangements for aggregate fiscal discipline can range from constitutional restraints on aggregate expenditure (e.g., Indonesia) through formal laws (e.g., Maastricht, New Zealand, Australia) to public commitments by the executives with or without the commitment of the legislature (e.g., U.S.). Incentive-based practices are followed in some countries like Sweden where the annual budget appropriations are deposited into each agency's interest-bearing account. Slow spending agencies get some interest earnings and the fast spenders have to pay interest. Also, to avoid the end-of-year spending surges, the agencies are allowed to carry forward their unused appropriations.

In the Indian context, public expenditure management has received focused attention as part of fiscal consolidation. An important institutional arrangement in this direction was the creation of the Expenditure Reform Commission to suggest measures to strengthen expenditure management. Following the recommendations of the Commission, the Government has taken several measures to contain expenditure growth and ensure efficiency in the expenditure management. The weak link in expenditure management, however, is cash management.

The pattern of expenditure reveals that for the last three years on an average, about 19 per cent of the total expenditure is incurred during the last month of the fiscal year. The pilot cash management system introduced in the Union Budget, 2003-04 adopts time-slicing of funds release to permit convergence of expenditure with the availability of resources within the year. Based on the actual requirement, monthly or quarterly cash limits for various ministries will be prescribed. The improved cash management is expected to avoid both mis-matches between receipts and expenditure and the rush of expenditure in the last quarter of the fiscal year.

References

  1. De Zoysa, Hemma R. (1990), Cash Management, in A. Premchand (ed), Government Financial Management-Issues and Country Studies, IMF.
  2. Premchand, A. (ed) (1990), Government Financial Management-Issues and Country Studies, IMF.
  3. World Bank (1998), Public Expenditure Management Handbook. http://www1.worldbank.org/publicsector. handbooks.htm.

4.6 Subsidies have almost doubled in the last five years with a sharp increase in 2002-03. Food and fertiliser subsidies account for 87.4 per cent of the expansion in subsidy spending since 1990-91. Food subsidy, mainly financing the buffer carrying cost and producers' subsidy, has been rising pari passu with the accumulation of foodstocks. The fiscal impact of the increase in foodgrain stocks is visible in the unprecedented expansion in food subsidies since 2000-01. On the other hand, the rationalisation of the Retention Price Scheme and enhancement of the maximum retail price of fertilisers has had positive effects on fertiliser subsidies. The budget for 2001-02 announced a phased programme of complete decontrol of the urea prices by April 1, 2006. The impact of these measures is reflected in the decline in fertiliser subsidies in recent years. Moreover, the emergence of petroleum subsidy since 2002-03 is the result of the dismantling of APM for petroleum products. The total subsidies are, however, high at 1.6 per cent of GDP in 2002-03, even after excluding the subsidy on the petroleum products (Table 4.3).

Table 4.3 : Expenditure on Subsidies by Major Heads

(Rupees crore)


Year

Food

Fertiliser

Interest

Petroleum

Other

Total Subsidies


1

2

3

4

5

6

7


1990-91

2,450

4,389

379

0

4,940

12,158

(0.4)

(0.8)

(0.1)

(0.9)

(2.1)

1991-92

2,850

5,185

316

0

3,902

12,253

(0.4)

(0.8)

(0.1)

(0.6)

(1.9)

1992-93

2,800

6,136

113

0

1,775

10,824

(0.4)

(0.8)

(0.2)

(1.4)

1993-94

5,537

5,079

113

0

876

11,605

(0.6)

(0.6)

(0.1)

(1.4)

1994-95

5,100

5,769

76

0

909

11,854

(0.5)

(0.6)

(0.1)

(1.2)

1995-96

5,377

6,735

34

0

520

12,666

(0.5)

(0.6)

(1.1)

1996-97

6,066

7,578

1,222

0

633

15,499

(0.4)

(0.6)

(0.1)

(1.1)

1997-98

7,900

9,918

78

0

644

18,540

(0.5)

(0.7)

(1.2)

1998-99

9,100

11,596

1,434

0

1,463

23,593

(0.5)

(0.7)

(0.1)

(0.1)

(1.4)

1999-2000

9,434

13,244

1,371

0

438

24,487

(0.5)

(0.7)

(0.1)

(1.3)

2000-01

12,060

13,800

111

0

867

26,838

(0.6)

(0.7)

(1.3)

2001-02

17,499

12,595

210

0

903

31,207

(0.8)

(0.5)

(1.4)

2002-03(RE)

24,200

11,009

765

6,265

2,379

44,618

(1.0)

(0.4)

(0.3)

(0.1)

(1.8)

2003-04(BE)

27,800

12,720

179

8,116

1,092

49,907

(1.0)

(0.5)

(0.3)

(1.8)


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

Note: Figures in brackets are per cent of GDP.

4.7 As mentioned before, earlier efforts at fiscal correction have resulted in a persistent decline in capital expenditure. In general, it is capital outlays which have provided the soft option for deficit-based fiscal correction. In the revised estimates for 2002-03, capital outlays fell short of the budgetary target by more than 25 per cent, implying the diversion of resources from productive investments to current expenditures. In the Indian context, there is considerable evidence that public investment has played a preponderant role in entrenching the conditions for higher growth. Moreover, expanding capital outlay in infrastructure has distinct salutary effects in terms of crowding in private investment. Under these circumstances, compression of capital outlay would inevitably affect asset creation and development of the physical infrastructure which holds the key to accelerated growth (Table 4.4).

Table 4.4 : Capital Expenditure of the Centre

(Rupees crore)


2002-03

2002-03

2001-02

1995-96

1990-91

Variation between RE

(RE)

(BE)

and BE (2002-03)


Amount

Per cent


1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8


Total Capital Expenditure

62,365

69,827

60,842

38,414

31,782

-7,462

-10.7

(1+2)=(3+4)

(2.5)

(2.7)

(2.6)

(3.2)

(5.6)

1. Capital Outlay

30,345

40,691

26,558

14,099

12,130

-10,346

-25.4

(1.2)

(1.6)

(1.2)

((1.2)

(2.1)

2. Loans and Advances

32,020

29,136

34,284

24,316

19,652

2,884

9.9

(1.3)

(1.1)

(1.5)

(2.0)

(3.5)

3. Non-Plan Capital

20,945

26,640

21,305

21,062

15,348

-5,695

-21.4

Expenditure

(0.8)

(1.0)

(0.9)

(1.8)

(2.7)

of which

Defence Capital

14,912

21,411

16,207

8,015

4,552

-6,499

-30.4

(0.6)

(0.8)

(0.7)

(0.7)

(0.8)

4. Plan Capital Expenditure (i+ii)

41,420

43,187

39,537

17,353

15,745

-1,767

-4.1

(1.7)

(1.7)

(1.7)

(1.5)

(2.8)

i) Central Plan Outlay

18,735

18,205

18,193

8,255

9,134

530

2.9

(0.8)

(0.7)

(0.8)

(0.7)

(1.6)

ii) Central Assistance

22,685

24,982

21,344

9,098

6,611

-2,297

-9.2

for State and UT Plans

(0.9)

(1.0)

(0.9)

(0.8)

(1.2)


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

Note: Figures in brackets are per cent of GDP.

Revenue Position

4.8 Various components of revenue receipts were impacted differentially by underlying macroeconomic conditions. The gap in revenue receipts vis-a-vis initial expectations was due to the fall in collections of direct taxes - individual income tax and corporation tax - as well as the Union excise duties. Both Union excise duties and corporation tax collections were, however, significantly higher than that in the preceding year, benefiting from the revival of industrial activity and the significant improvement in the financial performance of manufacturing companies. Customs duties benefited from the surge in import demand and posted a modest increase relative to budget estimates (Table 4.5).

Table 4.5 : Total Receipts of the Centre

(Rupees crore)


2002-03

2002-03

2001-02

1995-96

1990-91

Variation between RE

(RE)

(BE)

and BE (2002-03)


Amount

Per cent


1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

Total Receipts

4,04,013

4,10,309

3,62,453

1,68,468

93,951

-6,296

-1.5

(16.3)

(16.0)

(15.8)

(14.2)

(16.5)

Revenue Receipts

2,36,936

2,45,105

2,01,449

1,10,130

54,954

-8,169

-3.3

(9.6)

(9.6)

(8.8)

(9.3)

(9.7)

Tax Revenue (Net)

1,64,177

1,72,965

1,33,662

81,939

42,978

-8,788

-5.1

(6.6)

(6.8)

(5.8)

(6.9)

(7.6)

Non-Tax Revenue

72,759

72,140

67,787

28,191

11,976

619

0.9

(2.9)

(2.8)

(3.0)

(2.4)

(2.1)

Capital Receipts

1,67,077

1,65,204

1,61,004

58,338

38,997

1,873

1.1

(6.8)

(6.5)

(7.0)

(4.9)

(6.9)


Memo Items@


Corporation Tax

44,700

48,616

36,609

16,487

5,335

-3,916

-8.1

(1.8)

(1.9)

(1.6)

(1.4)

(0.9)

Income Tax

37,300

42,524

32,004

15,592

5,371

-5,224

-12.3

(1.5)

(1.7)

(1.4)

(1.3)

(0.9)

Customs Duty

45,500

45,193

40,268

35,757

20,644

307

0.7

(1.8)

(1.8)

(1.8)

(3.0)

(3.6)

Union Excise Duty

87,383

91,433

72,555

40,187

24,514

-4,050

-4.4

(3.5)

(3.6)

(3.2)

(3.4)

(4.3)


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

@ Memo items are on gross basis which include States’ share.

Note : Figures in brackets are per cent of GDP.

4.9 The tax-GDP ratio of the Centre has suffered steady deterioration from more than 10 per cent in late 1980s to just about 9 per cent in 2002-03, reflecting a decline in tax buoyancy1. Over the Eighth and Ninth Plan periods, the buoyancy of Central taxes deteriorated from 0.9 to 0.8 mainly on account indirect taxes; although the buoyancy in direct tax collection was maintained at 1.3, it has stagnated recent years and has not compensated adequately the fall in buoyancy of indirect taxes. The restructuring of both direct and indirect taxes effected since 1991 92, coupled with the structural shift in the composition of GDP towards the less-taxed services sector, appears to have affected the growth in tax revenue (Table 4.6)

Table 4.6 : Gross Tax Revenue of the Centre

(Per cent of GDP)


Years

Major Taxes

Gross Tax

Revenue

Income

Corporation

Excise

Customs

Tax

Tax

Duties

Duties


1

2

3

4

5

6


1990-91

0.9

0.9

4.3

3.6

10.1

1991-92

1.0

1.2

4.3

3.4

10.3

1992-93

1.1

1.2

4.1

3.2

10.0

1993-94

1.1

1.2

3.7

2.6

8.8

1994-95

1.2

1.4

3.7

2.6

9.1

1995-96

1.3

1.4

3.4

3.0

9.4

1996-97

1.3

1.4

3.3

3.1

9.4

1997-98

1.1

1.3

3.2

2.6

9.1

1998-99

1.2

1.4

3.1

2.3

8.3

1999-00

1.3

1.6

3.2

2.5

8.9

2000-01

1.5

1.7

3.3

2.3

9.0

2001-02

1.4

1.6

3.2

1.8

8.1

2002-03(RE)

1.5

1.8

3.5

1.8

9.0

2003-04(BE)

1.6

1.9

3.5

1.8

9.2


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

4.10 Non-tax revenue remained broadly unchanged at 3 per cent of GDP in 2002-03, unresponsive to the impulses of fiscal reforms However, the need for restructuring of public sector undertakings is critical, encompassing a thorough rationalisation of user charges and cost recoveries on the services rendered by the Government or entities in areas such as transport, power and irrigation. The Prime Minister's Economic Advisory Council (2002) had identified establishment rational user charges and credible regulatory authorities as the two critical features on which the success of infrastructure development will depend. The rationalisation of user charges covers utilities such as power, water and transport. User charges could be index-linked to input cost and a process of periodic revision should be automatic (Box IV.2).

Box IV.2
Pricing Policy for Public Services : The Dilemma of User Charges

The success of ensuring the critical physical infrastructure in the country depends on levying affordable and adequate user charges. In sectors like roads, telecommunications and ports where it has been possible to identify and levy proper user charges, overall growth has been noteworthy. Despite the well-known benefits of rationalising user charges to reflect true economic costs, progress in this direction has been impeded mainly by political economy considerations and the acute lack of the enabling legal architecture.

Taxation to cover the deficit is generally not favoured as an alternative to the raising of user charges. It is regarded as inequitable since everybody - not just the users of the public service - would be charged. Furthermore, while lump sum taxation to cover the deficit would not involve efficiency loss but it would be regressive. The Ramsey rule suggests that a mark-up (over the marginal cost) set in inverse proportion to the (compensated) price elasticity of demand for the product would minimise dead weight or efficiency loss.

Another solution to the policy dilemma is to charge a two-part tariff (a flat user fee which would be equivalent to a lump sum tax and hence would not involve any resource misallocation plus charge per unit of service) to those availing of the public service. Such techniques are used in the case of pricing of public utilities such as telephones, electricity and water supply.

Yet another technique is to apply price discrimination, wherein the consumer is charged a price equivalent to marginal cost at the last unit but higher prices for earlier units. Given the differences in the demand schedules of consumers, this would entail differential pricing as is evident in the case of electricity charges for residential and commercial groups.

In the case of public utility regulations, pricing is typically based on the principle of covering costs plus a fair return on capital, commensurate with that in respect of other industries. This is usually the case when public services are supplied in competition with private firms (which usually price the service above marginal cost). In accordance with the Theorem of the Second Best, setting price equivalent to marginal cost would be inefficient in other (public) sectors. In such cases, prices could be set equivalent to long-run average costs plus a normal return on capital. This would ensure fair competition and prevent high cost public producers from displacing more efficient low cost private producers.

Peak-load pricing involves charging higher user charges during periods of 'excess' demand and charging the marginal operating cost during off-peak periods (as was the case in respect of telephones in India). The same principle could be applied to address congestion on (toll) roads/bridges during peak hours. The pricing of negative externalities such as pollution is rendered much more difficult by the absence of adequate relevant information. Even so, efficient pricing involves adding the 'costs' of such externalities and setting the user charge equivalent to the marginal social cost.

In India, the need to raise user charges is underscored in the pricing of telecom services where it is seen as an essential ingredient of transition from a protected market to competition. As far as water pricing is concerned, a model based on capital, operation and maintenance costs has been attempted in some areas, although studies have shown that costs of water provision exceeded recovery in nearly 76 per cent of cities and towns in India. Cross-subsidisation of electricity charges in India has acted as a regressive tax on the commercial sector. Thus, electricity companies could recover only 68.6 per cent of their cost from the consumers. Proper pricing of power alone can reduce the financial burden of the state electricity boards and render them viable. As regards the railways, the fare freight ratio (earning per passenger Km. vis-a-vis earning per tonne Km.) continues to be one of the lowest in the world at 0.31 in 2001-02. Revenue losses of state road transport corporations were placed at around Rs.1,950 crore in 1999-2000.

Pricing and cost recovery policies have often not taken account of the fiscal effects and the cost of public funds. Setting user charges to economically efficient levels should, therefore, be the first priority for financing the economic infrastructure. Moreover, the user charges need to cover maintenance expenditures and control the level of services usage. Pricing policy should also address social concerns relating to public utilities and their long-term commercial viability.

References

  1. Baumol, W. and D. Bradford (1970), 'Optimal Departures from Marginal Cost Pricing', American Economic Review, June, Vol. 60, 265-83.
  2. McKinsey & Company (2001), India: The Growth Imperative, Vol. I, New Delhi.
  3. Mathur, O.P. (2001), Coming to Grips with Issues of Pricing Urban Water and Intra-City Bus Transport, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi.

4.11 The disinvestment programme made some progress during 2001-02 with the strategic sale process of some public sector undertakings gaining momentum; nevertheless the actual proceeds were lower than the targeted amount. In 2002-03, the disinvestment process remained below expectations. A major challenge facing the programme of public sector restructuring has been the closing down of persistently loss making and non-viable public sector undertakings (PSUs) so that the profitability of the other public enterprises could be a major source of resource generation to provide budgetary support. The stage is set for reforms in the PSUs by restructuring of potentially viable PSUs and improving the profitability and efficiency of the viable units. Priorities in reforms include raising return on investments in PSUs and infusing professionalisation in management (Box IV.3).

Box IV.3
Disinvestment Strategies and PSU Reform

The terms, 'disinvestment' and 'privatisation', are usually used interchangeably all over the world. In actuality, while 'disinvestment' represents sale of government share holding in PSUs, 'privatisation' is a more comprehensive concept and implies denationalisation including transfer of management and control to private entities. Widespread privatisation of PSUs has been a common phenomenon in both developing and developed countries in recent years, particularly as a response to their inefficient functioning and their adverse impact on State budgets. More than 100 countries across the globe have privatised some of their state-owned enterprises.

In India, initiatives have been taken over the years to enhance the efficiency and profitability of PSUs. Early PSU reforms focused on the creation of a buffer in the form of a holding company in line with the recommendations of the Committee to Review Policy for Public Enterprises (Chairman: Arjun Sengupta, 1984). Subsequently, a system of Memorandam of Understanding (MoU), imparting clarity to PSU objectives, was put in place.

The disinvestment process in India has evolved over more than a decade. The Government of India's Interim Budget for 1991-92 contained the first explicit statement on divestiture - the proposal to divest up to 20 per cent of the Government equity in select PSUs in favour of public sector institutional investors. A Disinvestment Commission was set up in 1996 and it recommended a shift from public offerings to strategic/trade sales with transfer of management in respect of a number of PSUs. The Union Budget of 1999-2000 provided clear guidelines for the classification of PSUs as strategic (defence-related, atomic energy related, railway transport) or non-strategic. A Department of Disinvestment was constituted in 1999 as a nodal department to streamline and speed up the process of disinvestment. Since 2000-01, major policy statements on disinvestment included closing down of PSUs which could not be revived, disinvestment in all non-strategic PSUs up to 74 per cent or higher and protection of workers' interest through safety nets. The Union Budget 2002-03 announced the completion of strategic sales in seven PSUs and some government-owned hotels and indicated that the shift in approach to strategic sales of blocks of shares to strategic investors (instead of disinvestments of small lots of shares) had enhanced the price/earnings (P/E) ratios. The policy on disinvestment announced in December 2002 specifically focused, inter alia, on the modernisation and upgradation of PSUs, creation of new assets, generation of employment, retiring of public debt, setting up a Disinvestment Proceeds and avoiding the emergence of private monopolies consequent upon disinvestment. The Union Budget 2003 04 has viewed the disinvestment process as a means unlocking the productive potential of the PSUs and reorienting the Government away from business towards the business of governance.

Reforms in PSUs have varied across industries in India The reform process in the power sector has envisaged privatisation of distribution, segregation of concentrated zones of high load density, competitive market structure and multi-tier regulation. The process, however, remains far from complete. Liberalisation of the telecommunication sector is substantially complete with the enactment of National Telecom Policy 1994, setting up of the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (TRAI) in 1997 and the Telecom Policy 1999 which has enabled the opening of almost all telecom services to the private sector. oil sector has also completed the first round disinvestment but the major stake is still with Government.

Out of 62 PSUs considered for disinvestment by Disinvestment Commission, the Central Government so far taken decisions to divest 49 PSUs. Out of 919 PSUs, the process of disinvestments/winding restructuring has been initiated for 221 units and process of privatisation has been completed for 33 units Realisation through disinvestment during 1991-stood at Rs.29,488 crore for the Centre as against a of Rs.78,300 crore, i.e., an achievement of about 38 cent of the target.

References

  1. Government of India, Ministry of Disinvestment, Website
  2. Lieberman, L. W. and D. Kirkness (eds) (1998), Privatisation and Emerging Equity Market Washington D.C., Flemings.
  3. World Bank (1995), 'Bureaucrats in Business: Economics and Politics of Government Ownership', Policy Research Report.

Overall deficit

4.12 The revised estimates for 2002-03 posted moderate slippages in the key indicators of the budgetary gap as initial expectations of higher growth in revenue collections and enhanced realisation from disinvestments were belied (Table 4.7).

Table 4.7 : Deficit Indicators of the Centre

(Rupees crore)


2002-03

2002-03

2001-02

1995-96

1990-91

Variation between RE

(RE)

(BE)

and BE (2002-03)


Amount

Per cent


1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8


Gross Fiscal Deficit

1,45,466

1,35,524

1,40,955

60,243

44,632

9,942

7.3

(5.9)

(5.3)

(6.1)

(5.1)

(7.8)

Revenue Deficit

1,04,712

95,377

1,00,162

29,731

18,562

9,335

9.8

(4.2)

(3.8)

(4.3)

(2.5)

(3.3)

Gross Primary Deficit

29,803

18,134

33,495

10,198

23,134

11,669

64.3

(1.2)

(0.7)

(1.5)

(0.9)

(4.1)


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

Note: Figures in brackets are per cent of GDP.

4.13 The persistence of fiscal stress limits the manoeuverability in revenue and expenditure policy and thereby restricts the scope of fiscal policy as a counter-cyclical tool. The committed nature of the expenditure and rigidities in the revenue side impede fiscal discretion in the context of the downturn phase of the business cycle (Box IV.4).

Box IV.4
Fiscal Stress and the Counter-Cyclical Policy

Fiscal policy influences economic activity through the operation of built-in or automatic stabilisers or through discretionary fiscal policy measures. In the short-run, automatic stabilisers, both on the revenue (progressive taxation) and expenditure side (unemployment insurance programme), would come into operation, ensuring efficiency in the system. Thus, in times of economic slowdown, the ideal policy stance is to accommodate a higher fiscal deficit since any effort to achieve a balanced budget target would turn out to be pro-cyclical. The problem with automatic stabilisers is, however, the persistence of 'deficit bias' as observed in several European countries. These countries adopted an expansionary fiscal stance in the times of slowdown but failed to restrict the expenditure in phase of recovery. It is also a fact that automatic stabilisers are more relevant only in industrialised economies with respect to the response of revenues to cyclical fluctuation in output. In developing countries, discretionary fiscal policy embodied in expenditure policies ensures effective counter cyclical response in times of slowdown. The basic theoretical underpinnings of the role of discretionary fiscal policy in stabilising the economy lie in the Keynesian framework where the government expenditure help the recovery of economic activity through revival of aggregate demand and multiplier effects.

The emergence of the European Monetary Union (EMU) represents a milestone in the historical evolution of fiscal policy. Its 'Stability and Growth Pact' seeks to strengthen the way for automatic stabilisers and balanced or surplus budgets as they would avoid structural deficits and consequent accumulation of the public debt. Countries like US, Japan and France reinforced the automatic stabilisers through an easy stance of fiscal policy in the 1990s recession. The tight stance of discretionary fiscal policy in some of the countries in the European Union, in fact, delayed the recovery from the 1993 recession. Countries like UK, Sweden and France have eased fiscal policy during the recession and tightened later. They achieved success in stabilising the economy but at the cost of fiscal positions that were weak in 1999 with substantially high debt-to-GDP ratios. In the US, on the other hand, fiscal policy acted as a powerful complement to automatic fiscal stabilisation and the desired result of stabilisation was achieved with a better debt position.

The fiscal position in India is marked by the persistence of the deficit. The structure of Government expenditure is skewed towards non-productive sectors. Committed expenditure like interest payments and wages and salaries has risen, leaving little scope for the Government to direct resources towards developmental and productive channels. The sluggish trend in revenues as also the committed nature of expenditure has constrained the use of fiscal policy to counter the slowdown in the economy. Empirical studies have shown that the fiscal deficit in India is mainly of a structural type and the cyclical component is negligible. The presence of a large structural deficit implies less scope for relying on automatic stabilisers.

References

  1. Buti, Marco; Hagen, Jurgen von and Matinez-Mongay, Carlos (2002). The Behaviour of Fiscal Authorities- Stabilisation, Growth and Institutions, Palgrave, New York.
  2. Noord, Paul van den (2002). Automatic Stabilisers in the 1990s and Beyond in Buti, Hagen and Matinez-Mongay (2002).
  3. Heller S. Peter (2002). Considering the IMF's Perspectives on a Sound Fiscal Policy, IMF Policy Discussion Paper, July.

STATE GOVERNMENT FINANCES, 2002-03

4.14 In recent years, the focus of fiscal reform has turned sub-national. It is increasingly recognised that it is the State finances where the government sector's interface with the people is most significant. Issues in the reform of fiscal policy in the States have a direct bearing on the quality of life.

4.15 The growth of revenue receipts of States during 2002-03 over the previous year was facilitated mainly by a rise in States' own taxes and grants from the Centre. Tax revenues were, however, affected by the slowing of activity in the wake of the drought. There were shortfalls in the States' own revenue receipts (tax and non tax revenue) as well as in States’ share in Central taxes in the revised estimates vis-a-vis budget estimates. In the States’ own taxes, the decline was mainly on account of sales tax collection; both States’ property taxes and income taxes exceeded the budget estimates. Under States’ non-tax revenue, receipts from State lotteries and interest receipts were lower in the revised estimates, while dividend and profits exceeded the budget estimates. Capital receipts of the States were higher on account of a rise in market borrowings and special securities issued to the National Small Saving Fund (Table 4.8).

Table 4.8 : Total Receipts of States

(Rupees crore)


2002-03

2002-03

2001-02

1995-96

1990-91

Variation between RE

(RE)

(BE)

and BE (2002-03)


Amount

Per cent


1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8


Total Receipts (1+2)

4,37,292

4,25,655

3,80,106

1,80,433

91,160

11,637

2.7

(17.7)

(16.6)

(16.6)

(15.2)

(16.0)

1. Revenue Receipts (a+b)

2,93,873

3,06,844

2,55,599

1,36,803

66,467

-12,971

-4.2

(11.9)

(12.0)

(11.1)

(11.5)

(11.7)

a)

Tax Revenue

2,02,518

2,15,049

1,80,275

92,913

44,586

-12,531

-5.8

(8.2)

(8.4)

(7.9)

(7.8)

(7.8)

States Taxes

1,49,358

1,52,590

1,31,710

63,865

30,344

-3,232

-2.1

( 6.0)

(6.0)

( 5.7)

(5.4)

( 5.3)

Sharable Taxes

53,160

62,459

48,565

29,048

14,242

-9,299

-14.9

(2.2)

(2.4)

(2.1)

(2.4)

(2.5)

b)

Non-Tax Revenue

91,355

91,795

75,324

43,891

21,881

-440

-0.5

(3.7)

(3.7)

(3.3)

(3.7)

(3.8)

Grants

55,401

54,008

43,048

20,996

12,643

1,393

2.6

(2.2)

(2.2)

(1.9)

(1.8)

( 2.2)

States Own Non-Taxes

35,954

37,787

32,276

22,895

9,238

-1,833

-4.9

(1.5)

(1.5)

(1.4)

(1.9)

(1.6)

2. Capital Receipts

1,43,419

1,18,811

1,24,507

43,630

24,693

24,608

20.7

(5.8)

(4.6)

(5.4)

(3.7)

(4.3)


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

Note:

Figures in brackets are per cent of GDP.

Source :

Budget Documents of State Governments.

4.16 Total expenditure in the revised estimates exceeded budget projections in 2002-03 on account of higher capital expenditure which rose to constitute one fifth of total expenditure of States. The increase in capital expenditure was mainly due to increases in the repayment of loans to the Centre and financial institutions reflecting the retirement of high cost debt owed to the Centre under the debt-swap scheme. Capital outlay in the revised estimates for 2002-03, however, fell short of budget estimates (Table 4.9).

Table 4.9 : Total Expenditure of the States

(Rupees crore)


2002-03

2002-03

2001-02

1995-96

1990-91

Variation between RE

(RE)

(BE)

and BE (2002-03)


Amount

Per cent


1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8


Total Expenditure (1+2)

4,42,609

4,30,842

3,77,555

1,77,584

91,088

11,767

2.7

(17.9)

(16.8)

(16.4)

(14.9)

(16.0)

1.

Revenue Expenditure

3,55,175

3,55,159

3,14,833

1,45,004

71,776

16

0.0

of which

(14.4)

(13.9)

(13.7)

(12.2)

(12.6)

Social Services

1,19,039

1,20,698

1,07,655

53,607

27,962

-1,659

-1.4

(4.8)

(4.7)

(4.7)

(4.5)

(4.9)

Economic Services

72,803

70,409

65,889

35,669

20,892

2,394

3.4

(2.9)

(2.8)

(2.9)

(3.0)

(3.7)

2.

Capital Expenditure

87,434

75,683

62,722

32,580

19,312

11,751

15.5

of Which

(3.5)

(3.0)

(2.7)

(2.7)

(3.4)

Capital Outlay

41,600

43,619

32,206

18,495

9,223

-2,019

-4.6

(1.7)

(1.7)

(1.4)

(1.6)

(1.6)


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

Note :

Figures in brackets are per cent of GDP.

Source :

Budget Documents of State Governments.

4.17 The revised estimates for 2002-03 indicate deviations in all major deficit indicators of State finances, with significant slippages in the revenue deficit as well as the primary deficit. Gross fiscal deficit was also higher in the revised estimate as compared with the budget estimates (Table 4.10).

Table 4.10 : Major Deficit Indicators of State Governments

(Rupees crore)


2002-03

2002-03

2001-02

1995-96

1990-91

Variation between RE

(RE)

(BE)

and BE (2002-03)


Amount

Per cent


1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8


Gross Fiscal Deficit

1,16,730

1,02,882

95,986

31,426

18,787

13,848

13.5

(4.7)

(4.0)

(4.2)

(2.6)

(3.3)

Revenue Deficit

61,302

48,314

59,233

8,201

5,309

12,988

26.9

(2.5)

(1.9)

(2.6)

(0.7)

(0.9)

Primary Deficit

42,584

30,629

33,497

9,494

10,132

11,955

39.0

(1.7)

(1.2)

(1.5)

(0.8)

(1.8)


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

Note : Figures in brackets are per cent of GDP.

Source: Budget Documents of State Governments.

4.18 A key issue in redrawing of boundaries between the public and the private sectors from the societal point of view is the physical and social infrastructure which provides the wherewithal for a durable improvement in standards of livelihood and significantly impacts the health of the State finances. In this regard, power sector reforms have assumed critical importance in recent years. The States of Andhra Pradesh, Delhi, Haryana, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa, Rajasthan, Uttar Pradesh and Uttaranchal have enacted State Electricity Reform Acts providing, inter alia, for unbundling/ corporatisation of State Electricity Boards (SEBs). Twenty one States have either constituted or notified the constitution of State Electricity Regulatory Commission (SERC). Twenty five States have signed tripartite agreements envisaged under the scheme for one-time settlement of outstanding dues payable by the SEBs to the Central Public Sector Undertakings (Box IV.5)

Box IV.5
Issues in Sub-National Fiscal Reforms

Fiscal reform at the State level has assumed critical importance in recent years and there is a heightened sensitivity all around, displayed in conscious policy decisions. In this context, it is important to take note of certain constraints faced by the States in achieving their fiscal goals. A large proportion of expenditure is of a committed nature. Declining buoyancies in tax and non-tax receipts, competitive sales taxes and related concessions have affected their financial position. Internal resource mobilisation by the States has been further constrained by losses incurred by the State Public Sector Undertakings, especially electricity boards and transport undertakings.

Many States have initiated measures such as setting up of consolidated sinking fund, guarantee redemption fund, statutory and administrative limits on guarantees. Other important initiatives relate to the preparatory work for introduction of Value Added Tax (VAT) and rationalisation of user charges mainly relating to power, water and transport. On the expenditure front, a number of States have proposed containment of revenue expenditure through restrictions on fresh recruitment/creation of new posts and curbs on the increase in administrative expenditure. Some States have proposed introduction of a contributory pension scheme for newly recruited staff. Some States have initiated measures to provide statutory backing to fiscal reforms through enabling legislation.

In recent years, States have initiated measures pertaining to PSU reforms. Maharashtra has constituted a Board for restructuring State PSUs, while States such as Punjab and Tamil Nadu have initiated measures for constituting disinvestment commissions. In regard to power sector reforms, measures taken by the States relate to the constitution of State Electricity Regulatory Commissions (SERCs) for determining the tariff structure, unbundling of electricity boards into separate entities for power generation, transmission and distribution, increasing power tariffs, measures for reducing transmission and distribution losses.

The Centre has also initiated measures to encourage fiscal reforms at the State level. Guided by the recommendations of the Eleventh Finance Commission, the Central Government has set up an Incentive Fund for encouraging fiscal reforms in the States on the basis of a monitorable fiscal reform programme. Under this scheme, the States draw up a Medium-Term Fiscal Reforms Programme (MTFRP) aimed at bringing down the fiscal deficit to sustainable levels. The Union Budget, 2002-03 made provision for reform-linked assistance of Rs.12,300 crore for States under various schemes such as Accelerated Power Development and Reform Programme (APDRP), Accelerated Irrigation Benefit Programme (AIBP), Urban Reforms Incentive Fund (URIF), and Rural Infrastructure Development Fund (RIDF). In addition, a lump sum amount of Rs.2,500 crore was proposed for implementing policy reforms in sectors which are constraining growth and development.

COMBINED BUDGETARY POSITION OF THE CENTRE AND STATES

4.19 The combined revenue receipts of the Centre and States recorded a shortfall from the budgeted level. The rise in non-tax revenue, albeit marginal, was inadequate to compensate the shortfall in tax collections. The combined capital receipts increased in the revised estimates partly due to additional market borrowings by the States under the debt swap scheme to prepay the high cost debt to the Centre. The combined aggregate expenditure exceeded the budget estimates on account of higher than anticipated revenue expenditure and loans and advances, while capital outlay (capital expenditure net of loans and advances) registered a decline. Developmental expenditure rose mainly on account of increased spending in the social sector. On the other hand, non-development expenditure (excluding others) was lower than the budgeted level due to reduction in interest payments and non-developmental capital outlay. The revised estimates for 2002-03 place all the major deficit indicators of the combined Government sector (Centre and States) higher than their budgeted levels (Table 4.11).

Table 4.11 : Indicators of Combined Finances of Centre and States*

(Rupees crore)


2002-03

2002-03

2001-02

1995-96

1990-91

Variation between RE

(RE)

(BE)

and BE (2002-03)


Items

Amount

Per cent


Centre

1,45,466

1,35,524

1,40,955

60,243

44,632

9,942

7.3

(5.9)

(5.3)

(6.1)

(5.1)

(7.8)

Gross Fiscal Deficit

States

1,16,730

1,02,882

95,986

31,426

18,787

13,848

13.5

(4.7)

(4.0)

(4.2)

(2.6)

(3.3)

Combined

2,48,979

2,26,864

2,26,418

77,671

53,580

22,115

9.7

(10.1)

(8.9)

(9.9)

(6.5)

(9.4)


Centre

1,04,712

95,377

1,00,162

29,731

18,562

9,335

9.8

(4.2)

(3.7)

(4.4)

(2.5)

(3.3)

Revenue Deficit

States

61,302

48,314

59,233

8,201

5309

12,988

26.9

(2.5)

(1.9)

(2.6)

(0.7)

(0.9)

Combined

1,66,014

1,43,691

1,59,395

37,932

23,871

22,323

15.5

(6.7)

(5.6)

(6.9)

(3.2)

(4.2)


Centre

29,803

18,134

33,495

10,198

23,134

11,669

64.3

(1.2)

(0.7)

(1.5)

(0.9)

(4.1)

Primary Deficit

States

42,584

30,629

33,497

9,494

10,132

11,955

39.0

(1.7)

(1.2)

(1.5)

(0.8)

(1.8)

Combined

88,492

64,442

84,048

18,598

28,585

24,050

37.3

(3.6)

(2.5)

(3.7)

(1.6)

(5.0)


Total Receipts (A+B)

7,46,601

7,36,538

6,55,907

2,96,629

1,52,398

10,063

1.4

A. Revenue Receipts (1+2)

4,71,600

4,90,665

4,00,229

2,17,527

1,05,757

-19,065

-3.9

1.

Tax Receipts (a+b)

3,66,696

3,88,015

3,13,937

1,74,852

87,564

-21,319

-5.5

a)

Direct Taxes

1,03,858

1,15,211

83,466

41,603

14,267

-11,353

-9.9

b)

Indirect Taxes

2,62,838

2,72,804

2,30,471

1,33,248

73,297

-9,966

-3.7

2.

Non-Tax Receipts

1,04,904

1,02,650

86,292

42,675

18,193

2,254

2.2

B. Capital Receipts (a+b)

2,75,001

2,45,873

2,55,678

79,102

46,641

29,128

11.8

a. Non-Debt Capital Receipts

14,657

19,726

18,158

6,968

3,233

-5,069

-25.7

b. Debt Capital Receipts

2,60,344

2,26,147

2,37,520

72,134

43,408

34,197

15.1

Aggregate Expenditure (4+5)

7,51,917

7,41,724

6,53,354

3,03,586

1,63,673

10,193

1.4

1. Revenue Expenditure

6,37,614

6,34,357

5,59,624

2,55,457

1,29,628

3,257

0.5

2. Capital Outlay

71,945

84,310

58,763

32,594

21,370

-12,365

-14.7

3. Loans and Advances

25,678

18,589

26,417

14,115

11,589

7,089

38.1

4. Development Expenditure

3,79,589

3,72,374

3,29,007

1,65,361

98,686

7,215

1.9

5. Non-Development Expenditure

3,72,329

3,69,350

3,24,348

1,38,225

64,987

2,979

0.8

(Including others)


RE : Revised Estimates.

BE : Budget Estimates.

* For States, data are provisional for the year 2001-02 onwards.

Notes :.

1

Figures in brackets are per cent of GDP.

2.

Combined GFD is the GFD of the Central Government plus GFD of the State Governments minus net lending from the Central Government to States.

3.

Revenue deficit is the difference between revenue receipts and revenue expenditure adjusted for inter- Governmental transactions in the revenue account.

4.

Gross primary deficit is defined as combined GFD minus combined interest payments.

RbiTtsCommonUtility

प्ले हो रहा है
শুনি আছে

RBI-Install-RBI-Content-Global

RbiSocialMediaUtility

ভাৰতীয় ৰিজাৰ্ভ বেংক মোবাইল এপ্পলিকেষ্যন ইনষ্টল কৰক আৰু নৱীনতম বাতৰিৰ প্ৰৱেশাধিকাৰ পাওক!

Scan Your QR code to Install our app

RbiWasItHelpfulUtility

এই পৃষ্ঠাটো সহায়ক আছিল নে?